Search Engine Manipulation Effect

SearchEngineManipulationEffect

Handy​ Easy Email and World News Links  WebMail
​GoogleSearch   INLTV.co.uk  YahooMail 

 HotMail   GMail   AOLMail  Twitter   

USAMAIL  WikiLeaks wikipedia.org  

Facebook   INLNews MyWayEmail  

INLNews  AWN.bz  

MagicRabbitAtThe2008NewYorkEasterParadeSayingILoveINLNews

 Magic Rabbit At The 2008 New York Easter Parade Saying

I Love www.INLNews.com and  www.inltv.co.uk

MrWorm-SlowerTailWagD20.gif

Paul_Rigby_1969_News-PAUL RIGBY_FamousAustralianCartoonist

Paul Rigby 1969 News-Famous Australian Cartoonist Hanging Out With His Little Geenie Mate ERF the Worm

Paul Crispen Rigby

 PAUL RIGBY Famous Australian Cartoonist

Paul Rigby 1969 News-Famous Australian Cartoonist Hanging Out With His Little Geenie Mate ERF the Worm

Paul Rigby
Paul Crispin Rigby was an Australian cartoonist who worked for newspapers in Australia, the United Kingdom, and the United States. He was born in Sandringham, Melbourne, Australia, on 25 October 1924, the second son of a telephone engineer. He studied Fine Art at Brighton Technical School in Melbourne and later worked as a commercial artist before taking up freelance work.
 

 ERFTheWormAnimationGiff18.gif

ERF The Worm Is Extremely Excited to be seeing his good mate Paul Rigby and Urchin

Paulrigbyurchin-Rigby'sTrademarkUrchin

 

ERF the Worm Is Telling Mr Wijat He Is Upset with Search Engine Manipulation

 

MrWorm-SlowerTailWagD20.gif

 

Mr Wijat and ERF The Worm Exposing Corrupt Search Engine Manipulation

"ERF ... how do you tell which search engines are corrupt and manipuplated?.." asks Mr Wijat

"Wijat... when your 'Controversial' article/website is 'Missing' from the ranking search list ." replies ERF the Worm

The search engine manipulation effect (SEME) is a change in consumer preferences from manipulations of search results by search engine providersIt is one of the largest behavioral effects ever discovered and includes voting preferencesThe effect works because searchers believe the web pages ranking high in Google to be true2Internet search rankings have a significant impact on consumer choices, mainly because users trust and choose higher-ranked results more than lower-ranked resultsBy manipulating search engine results to favor one candidate over another, voter preferences can be altered by 20 percent or more

Search Engine Manipulation Effect | Encyclopedia MDPI

Race To The  Moon1960's Paul Rigby Cartoon

Race To The  Moon1960's Paul Rigby Cartoon

MrWorm-SlowerTailWagD20.gif

 

 ERF the Worm's Head Moves Because ERF Is Exited To Tell His Friend Mr Wijat that ERF and His Other Good friend Paul Rigby have purchased a holiday villa on the Moon and will spend time together there with Paul Ribgy, Mr Wijat, Hal Wijat and Marven the Marvelous along with the other rarely seem member of Mr Wijat's Team, Magic Rabbit. Except of special occasions like the 2008 Easter Parade in 6th Avenue, New York City, New York State, USA, where Magic Rabbit appeared live in Magic Rabbit's special much Larger form, for the world to see. Normally only Mr Wijat can see Magic Rabbit through Mr Wijat's Special Sun Glasses designed and built by Marvif the Marvelous, so that Mr Wijat can see Magic Rabbit any time, through Mr Wijat's Special Magic Sunglasses.

 

MagicRabbit Appearing Out Of A Magician's Hat

Magic Rabbit

Magic Rabbit has psychic abilities, and warns Mr Wijat when trouble is looming for Mr Wijat

MagicRabbitAtThe2008NewYorkEasterParadeSayingILoveINLNews

 Magic Rabbit At The 2008 New York Easter Parade Saying

I Love www.INLNews.com and  www.inltv.co.uk

ERF the Worm's Head Moves Because ERF Is Exited To Tell His Friend Mr Wijat that ERF and His Other Good friend Paul Rigby have purchased a holiday villa on the Moon

Mr Wijat And ERF the Worm expose search engine manipulation

"ERF, how do you tell which search engines are corrupt and manipulated? ..ask Mr Wijat

"Wijat, it is when your 'Controversial' article or website is 'Missing or hidden way back on the 100th search engine page links.."...replies ERF the Worm 

We have done a web page on possible search engine corruption/manipulation of results listing such as on Google, Bing etc...we even proved this, our "Controversial' pages did not show in google & bing but did in other search engines such as yahoo.ie

we even proved this, our "Controversial' pges did not show in google & bing but did in other search engines such as yahoo.ie

"Oh...by the way Mr Hideit, I'm sure my corruption won't be listed on the search engines... just a little donation to helps matters.... "..says Mr. Deceitful ...

"Absolutely  no problems, Mr. Deceitful..."... replies Mr. Hideit

 

MrWorm-Animated-100times D19.gif

ERF Worm Is telling Mr Wijat very upset about Search Engine Manipulation and at the same time exited about his mate Paul Rigby's famous Inflation cartoon ... ERF and His Worm Family have been very concerned about the inflationary effect on quality Organic Humous, which is their stable food and the best organic manure for gardens and healthy soil, with ERF and His Worm Family eating the organic humous and and turning it into amazingly rich organic Worm Waste...

I'M SURE YOU'RE ALL DELIGHTED TO HEAR THERE WILL BE NO FREEZE-PaulRgby Inflation original cartoon artwork.TheSun_5thJuly1974

I'M SURE YOU'RE ALL DELIGHTED TO HEAR THERE WILL BE NO FREEZE-

Paul Rigby Inflation cartoon  5th July 1974

 

MrWormSaD21.gif

 

Meet Mr Wijat and His Team Working For Truth and Justice 

Mr Wijat And His Team Working For Truth And Justice And The Australian Way

Mr Wijat, work has dedicated his life to exposing and righting wrongs committed b y powerful people and powerful organisations against the defenseless little guy or gal, who have tried to abuse their power in a wrongful, immoral or unjust way...

 

 

Mr Wijat

ERFTheWormCrawling4.gif

ERF The Worm Is In a Happy Mood

ERFTheWormCrawl3.gif

ERF The Worm Crawling To Visit His Good Friend Mr Wijat

ERF the Worm, Mr Wijat's Little Greenie Mate

Paulrigbyurchin-Rigby'sTrademarkUrchin

Paul Rigby's Urchin - Paul Rigby's Trademark Urchin celebrating with His Little Geenie Mate ERF the Worm over exposing Search Engine Manipulation and others things which will be made public in future editions of the Australian Weekend News, the USA Weekend News INLtv.com and other INL News Group's newspapers and websites..

Paul Rigby and Urchin have always been great Western Australian friends form the very old days in the 1960's onwards... Paul Rigby created the very first cartoon for the first edition of the Australian Weekend News 

Al Wijat, Mr Wijat's Up Start Super Heron Life Saving Son

Marvin the Marvelous. who is Mr Wijat's Crazy Ideas man ... Marvin comes up with more than 100 plus ideas for Mr Wijat everyday ... but now and again Mr Wijat will say ..." Hey Marvin that is a great workable idea ... let's run with that idea.. and see how it goes..."

 

 

Click here for INL News Corp's most reliable, Wesite Hosting, Email and Affordable Domain Prices with Website Tonight Building Software For IT Dummies Like Mr Wijat To Be Able To Build A Website

Click Here For INL News Corporation Reliable, Safe Affordable Cheap Domains, Email and Cheap Web Hosting 

 

With INL News Corporation's Website Tonight Website Builder For Dummies It Is So Easy And Cheap To Own You Own Domain Name for as low as $5 And Build Your Own Website for As Low As $2 a week

 

Click Here for INL News Amazon Best Seller Books

INLNewsLimitedCorporateLogo

Rupert Murdoch In The 1960's
INLNewsLimitedCorporateLogo
INLNewsLimitedCorporateLogo
 
INL News Corp Limited Market Cap $80 Billion
93-95 CAMBRIDGE STREET Mitchell QLD 4465 | OO44774870057

World Uncensored News Information and Opinions

INL News Corp Limited Market Cap $80 Billion (internationalnewslimited.net)

The Australian Media Conspiracy

Click here to read more about the Australian Media Conspiracy

INLNewsLimitedCorporateLogo

INL News Corporation Limited

INL News Corporation Limited_LatestUncensoredNews

INL News Corporation Limited Bringing The World The Latest Uncensored News


INL News Corp Ltd Publications are not afraid of publishing the whole truth

Get The Latest Breaking News In Your INL Newspaper Now !!!!!! INL News Breaks the latest political Scandal Meet Mr Wijat and His Team fighting for Justice and Truth INTERNATIONAL NEWS LIMITED (INL News Corporation Limited) has been bringing entertaining uncensored real news, information and opinions to the World for over 30 years .

ITellYou,Boss-ifIts MondayThisMust BeMao_PaulRigbyCartoonC1-TedHeathPresidentRichardNixonOriginalCartoon Artwork

 I Tell You, Boss- .... if It's Monday This Must Be Mao  - Paul Rigby Cartoon 1970's

Ted Heath President Richard Nixon Cartoon Artwork

 

https://www.inltv.co.uk/images/Paul_Rigby_1969_News-PAUL%20RIGBY_FamousAustralianCartoonist_Ph1.jpg

Paul_Rigby_1969_News-PAUL RIGBY_FamousAustralianCartoonist

Paul Rigby

 PAUL RIGBY Famous Australian Cartoonist

Paul Rigby 1969 News-Famous Australian Cartoonist Hanging Out With His Little Geenie Mate ERF the Worm

Paul_Rigby_1969_News-PAUL RIGBY_FamousAustralianCartoonist

Paul Rigby

 PAUL RIGBY Famous Australian Cartoonist

Paul Rigby 1969 News-Famous Australian Cartoonist Hanging Out With His Little Geenie Mate ERF the Worm

The Australian Media Conspiracy

Click here to read more about the Australian Media Conspiracy

 The Australian Media Conspiracy is an extremely controversial book being published by the INL News and Australian Weekend News Publishing Group   based on a 30 plus year in depth INL News and Australian Weekend News Publishing Group Investigation Report into how immoral, unjust, devious, clandestine,  wrongful, and in many instances unlawful and illegal tactics and actions have been carried out by and/or for and on behalf of News Corp LLC, Keith Rupert Murdoch and his sons, Laughlan Murdoch and James Murdoch and the various directors and senior managers of News Corp LLC and its Australian controlled subsidiary publicly listed REA Group Limited ... which owns and controls the premium Australian Real Estate Advertising website

 

Click Here for INL News Amazon Best Seller Books

INLTV Uncensored News Logo

INLTV Uncensored News 

 

 

 

 

Click Here for INL News Amazon Best Seller Books

Rupert Murdoch's Sun King Endless Power please go to

RupertMurdochsEndlesspower (inltv.co.uk)

Click here to read about signs that you may be dealing with a pathological narcissist

https://inltv.co.uk/index.php/thesunking-rupertmurdoch-sendlessreignp2

TheSunKing_RupertMurdoch'sEndlessReign (inltv.co.uk)

https://inltv.co.uk/index.php/thesunking-rupertmurdoch-sendlessreign

Click Here for INL News Amazon Best Seller Books

INLTV Uncensored News Logo

INLTV Uncensored News 

INLTV is Easy To Find Hard To Leave

The New York Times - Breaking News, US News, World News and Videos (nytimes.com)

www.awn.bz Australian Weekend News  

https://www.nytimes.com/

"NewYorkTimesLatestNews" 

http://www.wikipediaexposed.org/newyorktimeslatestnews.html

Handy​ Easy Email and World News Links  WebMail
​GoogleSearch   INLTV.co.uk  YahooMail 

 HotMail   GMail   AOLMail  Twitter   

USAMAIL  WikiLeaks wikipedia.org  

Facebook   INLNews MyWayEmail  

INLNews  AWN.bz  

Sponsored Website Log in Link  

Bahai.org  AustralianDailyNews  USAToday  

EuropeanNews   WashingtonPostNews

vice.com  kanalukraina.tv   RussianNews-themoscowtimes.com  RussiaBeyond   rt.com  AWNNews    themindunleashed.com       TheList.com   gossip.whyfame   crikey.com.au tsarizm.com  zergnet.com CDMedia ReutersNewsVideos   CNNWorld   JapaneseNews  VestiNews IsraelVideoNews NewYorkTimes   BBCNews  TheTimesUK   c-span.org   icepop.com
WashingtonPostNews   WashingtonTimesNews  ChinaDailyNews   AdelaideNews  The Guardian-News  ABCAustralianNews   reason.com    reason.com/video  NewZealandNews   USADailyNews   Indian News   Queensland News​    Melbourne News    SydneyNews-SydneyMorningHerald     DarwinNews
SydneyDailyNews-Daily Telegraph  truthwiki.org  themindunleashed.com  aljazeera.com  spyurk.am
WesternAustralianNews  wikipediocracy.com   tcij.org  aljazeera.com/investigations  hindustantimes
​spiked-online.com-humanity is underrated  TheVerge   The Truth Factory   newsfollowup.com
encyclopediadramatica.rs  themarysue.com  huffpost  consciouslifenews.com  collective-evolution.com

WesternAustralianNews  wikipediocracy.com   tcij.org  aljazeera.com/investigations  

hindustantimes

​spiked-online.com-humanity is underrated  TheVerge   The Truth Factory   newsfollowup.com

encyclopediadramatica.rs  themarysue.com  huffpost  consciouslifenews.com  

collective-evolution.com

INLNews Sponsored Website Log in Link   rightsinfo.org   Progressive.org  www.vox.com 

forensic-architecture.org   www.c-span.org   wikispooks.com  newint.org   progressive.org

​Popular-Amazing-WILD-AnimalEncounters-FailCompilations-awn.bz  www.rawstory.com  counterpunch.org 

 collective-evolution.com   theduran.com  truthdig.com   LibertyNews

 

More Great World News Links
 
World Liberal News Links

Conservative News

 

MA

RC AMBINDER
JONATHAN

ALTER
PAUL BEDARD
GLORIA BORGER

DAVID BRODER

DAVID BROOKS
ELEANOR CLIFT

MARIE COCCO
RICHARD COHEN
JOE CONASON
DAVID CORN
CRAIG CR

 

AWFORD
STANLEY CROUCH
DE BORCHGRAVE

MAUREEN DOWD
KEVIN DRUM
SUSAN ESTRICH
HOWARD FINEMAN
GEORGIE GEYER
ELLEN GOODMAN
MARK HALPERIN
PAUL KRUGMAN 
BILL PRESS
CARL HIAASEN
NAT HENTOFF
PEREZ HILTON
CHRISTOPHER HITCHENS
AL KAMEN
BRENT BOZELL III 
PAT BUCHANAN
HOWIE CARR 
MONA CHAREN
LINDA CHAVEZ
ANN COULTER
LOU DOBBS
LARRY ELDER 

 

OSEPH FARAH 
SUZANNE FIELDS 
JOHN FUND 
MAGGIE GALLAGHER
BILL GERTZ
JONAH GOLDBERG 
SEAN HANNITY 
HUGH HEWITT  
LARRY KUDLOW
DAVID LIMBAUGH 
RUSH LIMBAUGH 
HAL LINDSEY
RICH LOWRY
MICHELLE MALKIN

JOHN McCASLIN
CHARLES KRAUTHAMMER
BOB NOVAK
MARVIN OLASKY
GREG PIERCE

JIM PINDERTON 
WESLEY PRUDEN 
BILL O'REILLY
ROBERTS/ARGETSINGER
DICK MORRIS
MICHAEL SNEED 
JOE SOBRAN 
THOMAS SOWELL
MARK STEYN 
CAL THOMAS 
GEORGE WILL
WALTER WILLIAMS
PHYLLIS SCHLAFLY

 

AP WORLD  AP NATIONAL  AP WASHINGTON  AP BUSINESS  AP ENTERTAINMENT
AP ON THE HOUR  AP HEADLINES  AP BREAKING AP REUT PHOTO WIRE
AP AUDIO 
ABCNEWS   ABCNEWS THE NOTE  AD AGE DEADLINE
BBC  BBC AUDIO  C-SPAN

CHICAGO TRIB   CHICAGO SUN-TIMES  CHRISTIAN SCIENCE
CNN  CNN POLITICAL TICKER
DAILY SWARM   DAILY VARIETY
ECONOMIST  EDITOR & PUBLISHER
BILLBOARD   BOSTON GLOBE  BOSTON HERALD   BREITBART
CBS NEWS    EMIRATES TODAY   FORBES  FOX NEWS
FREE REPUBLIC   HOT AIR   HILL  HUMAN EVENTS   IAFRICA
INTERNATIONAL HERALD    INVEST BUS DAILY    JERUSALEM POST
JEWISH WORLD REVIEW  LA DAILY NEWS    LA TIMES     MEDIA WEEK 
MSNBC    MSNBC FIRST READ     NATIONAL REVIEW   NEW REPUBLIC   NEW YORK
NY DAILY NEWS    NY OBSERVER    NY POST    NY SUN    NY TIMES
NEW YORKER    NEWSBUSTERS    NEWSBYTES     NEWSMAX    NEWSWEEK
N. KOREAN NEWS    PHILLY INQUIRER   PHILLY DAILY NEWS 

POLITICO    R & R      RADAR 
REAL CLEAR POLITICS      REASON MAG        ROLL CALL
SAN FRAN CHRON       SKY NEWS
SLATE      SMOKING GUN      SPLASH NEWS
SYDNEY HERALD
U.K. DAILY MAIL      U.K.DAILY MIRROR      DAILY RECORD
U.K.EVENING STANDARD     U.K.EXPRESS
U.K.GUARDIAN     U.K.INDEPENDENT      U.K.LONDON PAPER 
U.K.NEWS OF THE WORLD     U.K.SUN     U.K.TELEGRAPH       U.K.TIMES
US NEWS        USA TODAY
VILLAGE VOICE       WASH POST       WASHINGTON TIMES
WEEKLY STANDARD         WORLDNETDAILY

INL News Corp Limited Market Cap $80 Billion
93-95 CAMBRIDGE STREET Mitchell QLD 4465 | OO44774870057

World Uncensored News Information and Opinions

INL News Corp Limited Market Cap $80 Billion (internationalnewslimited.net)

The Australian Media Conspiracy

Click here to read more about the Australian Media Conspiracy

INLNewsLimitedCorporateLogo

INL News Corporation Limited

INL News Corporation Limited_LatestUncensoredNews

INL News Corporation Limited Bringing The World The Latest Uncensored News


INL News Corp Ltd Publications are not afraid of publishing the whole truth

Get The Latest Breaking News In Your INL Newspaper Now !!!!!! INL News Breaks the latest political Scandal Meet Mr Wijat and His Team fighting for Justice and Truth INTERNATIONAL NEWS LIMITED (INL News Corporation Limited) has been bringing entertaining uncensored real news, information and opinions to the World for over 30 years .

 

Search Engine Manipulation Effect

The search engine manipulation effect (SEME) is a change in consumer preferences from manipulations of search results by search engine providersIt is one of the largest behavioral effects ever discovered and includes voting preferencesThe effect works because searchers believe the web pages ranking high in Google to be true2Internet search rankings have a significant impact on consumer choices, mainly because users trust and choose higher-ranked results more than lower-ranked resultsBy manipulating search engine results to favor one candidate over another, voter preferences can be altered by 20 percent or more

The search engine manipulation effect (SEME) is the change in consumer preferences from manipulations of search results by search engine providers. SEME is one of the largest behavioral effects ever discovered. This includes voting preferences. A 2015 study indicated that such manipulations could shift the voting preferences of undecided voters by 20 percent or more and up to 80 percent in some demographics.

The study estimated that this could change the outcome of upwards of 25 percent of national elections worldwide.

On the other hand, Google denies secretly re-ranking search results to manipulate user sentiment, or tweaking ranking specially for elections or political candidates

1. Scenarios

At least three scenarios offer the potential to shape/decide elections. The management of a search engine could pick a candidate and adjust search rankings accordingly. Alternatively, a rogue employee who has sufficient authority and/or hacking skills could surreptitiously adjust the rankings. Finally, since rankings influence preferences even in the absence of overt manipulation, the ability of a candidate to raise his or her ranking via traditional search engine optimization would influence voter preferences. Simple notoriety could substantially increase support for a candidate. [1]

2. Experiments

Five experiments were conducted with more than 4,500 participants in two countries. The experiments were randomized (subjects were randomly assigned to groups), controlled (including groups with and without interventions), counterbalanced (critical details, such as names, were presented to half the participants in one order and to half in the opposite order) and double-blind (neither subjects nor anyone who interacted with them knows the hypotheses or group assignments). The results were replicated four times. [1]

2.1. US

In experiments conducted in the United States, the proportion of people who favored any candidate rose by between 37 and 63 percent after a single search session.[1]

Participants were randomly assigned to one of three groups in which search rankings favored either Candidate A, Candidate B or neither candidate. Participants were given brief descriptions of each candidate and then asked how much they liked and trusted each candidate and whom they would vote for. Then they were allowed up to 15 minutes to conduct online research on the candidates using a manipulated search engine. Each group had access to the same 30 search results—each linking to real web pages from a past election. Only the ordering of the results differed in the three groups. People could click freely on any result or shift between any of five different results pages.[1]

After searching, on all measures, opinions shifted in the direction of the candidate favored in the rankings. Trust, liking and voting preferences all shifted predictably. 36 percent of those who were unaware of the rankings bias shifted toward the highest ranked candidate, along with 45 percent of those who were aware of the bias.[1]

Slightly reducing the bias on the first result page of search results – specifically, by including one search item that favoured the other candidate in the third or fourth position masked the manipulation so that few or even no subjects noticed the bias, while still triggering the preference change.[2]

Later research suggested that search rankings impact virtually all issues on which people are initially undecided around the world. Search results that favour one point of view tip the opinions of those who are undecided on an issue. In another experiment, biased search results shifted people’s opinions about the value of fracking by 33.9 per cent.[2]

2.2. India

A second experiment involved 2,000 eligible, undecided voters throughout India during the 2014 Lok Sabha election. The subjects were familiar with the candidates and were being bombarded with campaign rhetoric. Search rankings could boost the proportion of people favoring any candidate by more than 20 percent and more than 60 percent in some demographic groups.[1]

2.3. United Kingdom

A UK experiment was conducted with nearly 4,000 people just before the 2015 national elections examined ways to prevent manipulation. Randomizing the rankings or including alerts that identify bias had some suppressive effects.[1]

3. European Antitrust Lawsuit

European regulators accused Google of manipulating its search engine results to favor its own services, even though competitive services would otherwise have ranked higher. As of August 2015, the complaint had not reached resolution, leaving the company facing a possible fine of up to $6 billion and tighter regulation that could limit its ability to compete in Europe. In November 2014 the European Parliament voted 384 to 174 for a symbolic proposal to break up the search giant into two pieces—its monolithic search engine and everything else.[3]

The case began in 2009 when Foundem, a British online shopping service, filed the first antitrust complaint against Google in Brussels. In 2007, Google had introduced a feature called Universal Search. A search for a particular city address, a stock quote, or a product price returned an answer from one of its own services, such as Google Maps or Google Finance. This saved work by the user. Later tools such as OneBox supplied answers to specific queries in a box at the top of search results. Google integrated profile pages, contact information and customer reviews from Google Plus. That information appeared above links to other websites that offered more comprehensive data, such as Yelp or TripAdvisor.[3]

Google executives Larry Page and Marissa Mayer, among others, privately advocated for favoring Google’s own services, even if its algorithms deemed that information less relevant or useful.[3]

Google acknowledges adjusting its algorithm 600 times a year, but does not disclose the substance of its changes.[1]

4. 2016 Presidential Election

In April 2015, Hillary Clinton hired Stephanie Hannon from Google to be her chief technology officer. In 2015 Eric Schmidt, chairman of Google's holding company started a company – The Groundwork – for the specific purpose of electing Clinton. Julian Assange, founder of WikiLeaks, called Google her ‘secret weapon’. Researchers estimated that Google could help her win the nomination and could deliver between 2.6 and 10.4 million general election votes to Clinton via SEME. No evidence documents any such effort, although since search results are ephemeral, evidence could only come via a Google whistleblower or an external hacker.[2]

On June 9, 2016, SourceFed alleged that Google manipulated its searches in favor of Clinton because the recommended searches for her are different than the recommended searches to both Yahoo and Bing and yet the searches for both Donald Trump and Bernie Sanders are identical to both Yahoo and Bing. When "Hillary Clinton Ind" was entered in the search bar, Google Autocomplete suggested "Hillary Clinton Indiana", while the other vendors suggested "Hillary Clinton indictment". Furthermore, SourceFed placed the recommended searches for Clinton on Google Trends and observed that the Google suggestion was searched less than the suggestion from the other vendors.[4][5][6] 

References

  1. Epstein, Robert (August 19, 2015). "How Google Could Rig the 2016 Election". Politico.com. http://www.politico.com/magazine/story/2015/08/how-google-could-rig-the-2016-election-121548.html?hp=rc3_4#.VduFK6sVhhH. Retrieved 2015-08-24. 
  2. "How the internet flips elections and alters our thoughts — Robert Epstein — Aeon Essays". https://aeon.co/essays/how-the-internet-flips-elections-and-alters-our-thoughts
  3. Silver, Vernon; Stone, Brad (August 6, 2015). "Google’s $6 Billion Miscalculation on the EU". https://www.bloomberg.com/news/features/2015-08-06/google-s-6-billion-miscalculation-on-the-eu. Retrieved 2015-08-25. 
  4. Hern, Alex (10 June 2016). "Google Manipulating Search In Favor Of Hillary Clinton?". http://techaeris.com/2016/06/10/google-manipulating-results-favor-hillary-clinton/. Retrieved 10 June 2016. 
  5. Richardson, Valerie (9 June 2016). "Google accused of burying negative Hillary Clinton stories". The Washington Times. http://www.washingtontimes.com/news/2016/jun/9/google-accused-burying-negative-hillary-clinton-st/. Retrieved 10 June 2016. 
  6. TAKALA, RUDY (2016-06-11). "Google denies manipulating search results to favor Hillary Clinton". http://www.washingtonexaminer.com/google-appears-to-be-manipulating-search-results-to-help-hillary-clinton/article/2593562
 
Related Entries
Google+
Google Plus (stylized as Google+) is an Internet-based social network that is owned and operated by Google. The service, Google's fourth foray into social networking, experienced strong growth in its initial years, although usage statistics have varied, depending on how the service is defined. Three Google executives have overseen the service, which has undergone substantial changes leading to a redesign in November 2015. On October 8, 2018, Google announced that it was shutting down Google+ for consumers, citing low user engagement and a software error, first reported by The Wall Street Journal , that potentially exposed the data of hundreds of thousands of users. Google indicated that Google+ would operate until August 2019, allowing users to download and migrate their information.
Keywords: social networkuser engagementgoogle
Hootsuite
Hootsuite is a social media management platform, created by Ryan Holmes in 2008. The system’s user interface takes the form of a dashboard, and supports social network integrations for Twitter, Facebook, Instagram, LinkedIn, Google+ and YouTube. Additional integrations are available via Hootsuite’s App Directory, including Reddit, Storify, Tumblr, and Marketo. Based in Vancouver , Hootsuite has close to 1,000 staff members located in 13 locations, including Toronto, Bucharest and Mexico City. The company has more than 15 million users in over 175 countries.
Keywords: social mediasocial networkhootsuite
Influencer Marketing
Influencer marketing (also known as influence marketing) is a form of social media marketing involving endorsements and product placement from influencers, people and organizations who have a purported expert level of knowledge or social influence in their field. Influencers are someone (or something) with the power to affect the buying habits or quantifiable actions of others by uploading some form of original—often sponsored—content to social media platforms like Instagram, YouTube, Snapchat or other online channels. Influencer marketing is when a brand enrolls influencers who have an established credibility and audience on social media platforms to discuss or mention the brand in a social media post. Influencer content may be framed as testimonial advertising.
Keywords: social media marketingsocial media platformssocial media
Moz (Marketing Software)
Moz is a software as a service (SaaS) company based in Seattle that sells inbound marketing and marketing analytics software subscriptions. It was founded by Rand Fishkin and Gillian Muessig in 2004 as a consulting firm and shifted to SEO software development in 2008. The company hosts a website that includes an online community of more than one million globally based digital marketers and marketing related tools. Moz offers SEO tools that includes keyword research, link building, site audits, and page optimization insights in order to help companies to have a better view of the position they have on search engines and how to improve their ranking. The company also developed the most commonly used algorithm to determine Domain Authority, which is a score between 1-100, that is often used by many SEO companies to estimate a website's overall viability with the search engines.
Keywords: software as a serviceinbound marketingsoftware development
Social Information Seeking
Social information seeking (SIS) is a field of research that involves studying situations, motivations, and methods for people seeking and sharing information in participatory online social sites, such as Yahoo! Answers, Answerbag, WikiAnswers and Twitter as well as building systems for supporting such activities. Highly related topics involve traditional and virtual reference services, information retrieval, information extraction, and knowledge representation.
Keywords: online socialvirtual referenceinformation seeking
Weibo.com
Sina Weibo (NASDAQ: WB) (新浪微博) is a Chinese microblogging (weibo) website. Launched by Sina Corporation on 14 August 2009, it is one of the biggest social media platforms in China, with over 445 million monthly active users as of Q3 2018. The platform has been a huge financial success, with surging stocks, lucrative advertising sales and high revenue and total earnings per quarter. At the start of 2018, it surpassed the US$30 billion market valuation mark for the first time. In March 2014, Sina Corporation announced a spinoff of Weibo as a separate entity and filed an IPO under the symbol WB. Sina carved out 11% of Weibo in the IPO, with Alibaba owning 32% post-IPO. The company began trading publicly on 17 April 2014. In March 2017, Sina launched Sina Weibo International Version. This new version has a clean, concise user interface design, as well as an ad-free feature; while its volume is very small, only occupying one-fifth of the space of the original, it still performs all of the original's functions. In June 2018, Sina Weibo reached 413 million active users. In November 2018, Sina Weibo suspended its registration function for minors under the age of 14. In July 2019, Sina Weibo announced that it would launch a two-month campaign to clean up pornographic and vulgar information, named The Blue Plan. Sina Weibo has attracted criticism over censoring its users.
Keywords: social media platformsmicroblogging新浪微博
Sina Weibo
Sina Weibo (NASDAQ: WB) (新浪微博) is a Chinese microblogging (weibo) website. Launched by Sina Corporation on 14 August 2009, it is one of the biggest social media platforms in China, with over 445 million monthly active users as of Q3 2018. The platform has been a huge financial success, with surging stocks, lucrative advertising sales and high revenue and total earnings per quarter. At the start of 2018, it surpassed the US$30 billion market valuation mark for the first time. In March 2014, Sina Corporation announced a spinoff of Weibo as a separate entity and filed an IPO under the symbol WB. Sina carved out 11% of Weibo in the IPO, with Alibaba owning 32% post-IPO. The company began trading publicly on 17 April 2014. In March 2017, Sina launched Sina Weibo International Version. This new version has a clean, concise user interface design, as well as an ad-free feature; while its volume is very small, only occupying one-fifth of the space of the original, it still performs all of the original's functions. In June 2018, Sina Weibo reached 413 million active users. In November 2018, Sina Weibo suspended its registration function for minors under the age of 14. In July 2019, Sina Weibo announced that it would launch a two-month campaign to clean up pornographic and vulgar information, named The Blue Plan. Sina Weibo has attracted criticism over censoring its users.
Keywords: social media platformsmicroblogging新浪微博
News Feed
News Feed is a feature of the social network Facebook. The web feed is the primary system through which users are exposed to content posted on the network. News Feed highlights information that includes profile changes, upcoming events, and birthdays, among other updates. Using a proprietary method, Facebook selects a handful of updates to show users every time they visit their feed, out of an average of 2,000 updates they can potentially receive. Over two billion people use Facebook every month, making the network's News Feed the most viewed and most influential aspect of the news industry.
Keywords: the social networkfacebookprofile
The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics
The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (2008), 2nd ed., is an eight-volume reference work on economics, edited by Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume and published by Palgrave Macmillan. It runs to 7,680 pages and 5.8 million words. It includes 1,844 articles, of which 1057 are new articles and, from the earlier edition, 80 "classic" essays, 157 revised articles, and 550 edited articles. It is the product of 1,506 contributors, 25 of them Nobel Laureates in Economics. Articles are classified according to Journal of Economic Literature (JEL) classification codes. The New Palgrave is also available in a hyperlinked online version. Article information by abstract, outline, and keywords is available without subscription. These are accessed by "Go to" or "Quick" searches or alphabetical article links by first letter, see Articles A-Z. Refined search by using JEL classification code, article elements, Boolean operators, or wildcards is available, see Advanced search. Online content is added to the 2008 edition from quarterly updates links, see Online Updates. The first edition was titled The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (1987), edited by John Eatwell, Murray Milgate, and Peter Newman and published in four volumes. It is discussed in a section below. Access to full-text articles for both editions and post-2008 updates is available online by subscription, whether of an organization, a person, or a person through an organization.
Keywords: classificationbooleaneconomics
Cross-Platform User-Generated Content
User-generated content (UGC) from e-commerce platforms and third-party platforms can impact customer-perceived risk and influence product sales in online stores. However, the understanding of UGC from which platform type yields a stronger effect on product sales and how the effects interact across the platforms remains limited, especially from a cross-platform UGC perspective. 
Keywords: cross-platform UGCsentiment analysiselaboration likelihood model
Social:Search engine manipulation effect - HandWiki

Scenarios

At least three scenarios offer the potential to shape/decide elections. The management of a search engine could pick a candidate and adjust search rankings accordingly. Alternatively, a rogue employee who has sufficient authority and/or hacking skills could surreptitiously adjust the rankings. Finally, since rankings influence preferences even in the absence of overt manipulation, the ability of a candidate to raise his or her ranking via traditional search engine optimization would influence voter preferences. Simple notoriety could substantially increase support for a candidate.[1]

Experiments

Five experiments were conducted with more than 4,500 participants in two countries. The experiments were randomized (subjects were randomly assigned to groups), controlled (including groups with and without interventions), counterbalanced (critical details, such as names, were presented to half the participants in one order and to half in the opposite order) and double-blind (neither subjects nor anyone who interacted with them knows the hypotheses or group assignments). The results were replicated four times.[1]

US

In experiments conducted in the United States, the proportion of people who favored any candidate rose by between 37 and 63 percent after a single search session.[1]

Participants were randomly assigned to one of three groups in which search rankings favored either Candidate A, Candidate B or neither candidate. Participants were given brief descriptions of each candidate and then asked how much they liked and trusted each candidate and whom they would vote for. Then they were allowed up to 15 minutes to conduct online research on the candidates using a manipulated search engine. Each group had access to the same 30 search results—each linking to real web pages from a past election. Only the ordering of the results differed in the three groups. People could click freely on any result or shift between any of five different results pages.[1]

After searching, on all measures, opinions shifted in the direction of the candidate favored in the rankings. Trust, liking and voting preferences all shifted predictably. 36 percent of those who were unaware of the rankings bias shifted toward the highest ranked candidate, along with 45 percent of those who were aware of the bias.[1]

Slightly reducing the bias on the first result page of search results – specifically, by including one search item that favoured the other candidate in the third or fourth position masked the manipulation so that few or even no subjects noticed the bias, while still triggering the preference change.[4]

Later research suggested that search rankings impact virtually all issues on which people are initially undecided around the world. Search results that favour one point of view tip the opinions of those who are undecided on an issue. In another experiment, biased search results shifted people’s opinions about the value of fracking by 33.9 per cent.[4]

India

A second experiment involved 2,000 eligible, undecided voters throughout India during the 2014 Lok Sabha election. The subjects were familiar with the candidates and were being bombarded with campaign rhetoric. Search rankings could boost the proportion of people favoring any candidate by more than 20 percent and more than 60 percent in some demographic groups.[1]

United Kingdom

A UK experiment was conducted with nearly 4,000 people just before the 2015 national elections examined ways to prevent manipulation. Randomizing the rankings or including alerts that identify bias had some suppressive effects.[1]

European antitrust lawsuit

European regulators accused Google of manipulating its search engine results to favor its own services, even though competitive services would otherwise have ranked higher. As of August 2015, the complaint had not reached resolution, leaving the company facing a possible fine of up to $6 billion and tighter regulation that could limit its ability to compete in Europe. In November 2014 the European Parliament voted 384 to 174 for a symbolic proposal to break up the search giant into two pieces—its monolithic search engine and everything else.[5]

The case began in 2009 when Foundem, a British online shopping service, filed the first antitrust complaint against Google in Brussels. In 2007, Google had introduced a feature called Universal Search. A search for a particular city address, a stock quote, or a product price returned an answer from one of its own services, such as Google Maps or Google Finance. This saved work by the user. Later tools such as OneBox supplied answers to specific queries in a box at the top of search results. Google integrated profile pages, contact information and customer reviews from Google Plus. That information appeared above links to other websites that offered more comprehensive data, such as Yelp or TripAdvisor.[5]

Google executives Larry Page and Marissa Mayer, among others, privately advocated for favoring Google’s own services, even if its algorithms deemed that information less relevant or useful.[5]

Google acknowledges adjusting its algorithm 600 times a year, but does not disclose the substance of its changes.[1]

2016 Presidential election

In April 2015, Hillary Clinton hired Stephanie Hannon from Google to be her chief technology officer. In 2015 Eric Schmidt, chairman of Google's holding company started a company – The Groundwork – for the specific purpose of electing Clinton. Julian Assange, founder of WikiLeaks, called Google her ‘secret weapon’. Researchers estimated that Google could help her win the nomination and could deliver between 2.6 and 10.4 million general election votes to Clinton via SEME. No evidence documents any such effort, although since search results are ephemeral, evidence could only come via a Google whistleblower or an external hacker.[4]

On June 9, 2016, SourceFed alleged that Google manipulated its searches in favor of Clinton because the recommended searches for her are different than the recommended searches to both Yahoo and Bing and yet the searches for both Donald Trump and Bernie Sanders are identical to both Yahoo and Bing. When "Hillary Clinton Ind" was entered in the search bar, Google Autocomplete suggested "Hillary Clinton Indiana", while the other vendors suggested "Hillary Clinton indictment". Furthermore, SourceFed placed the recommended searches for Clinton on Google Trends and observed that the Google suggestion was searched less than the suggestion from the other vendors.[6][7][8]

References

  1. ↑ Jump up to:1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.8 Epstein, Robert (August 19, 2015). "How Google Could Rig the 2016 Election". Politico.com. Retrieved 2015-08-24.
  2.  Epstein, Robert; Robertson, Ronald E. (2015-08-18). "The search engine manipulation effect (SEME) and its possible impact on the outcomes of elections" (in en). Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 112 (33): E4512–E4521. doi:10.1073/pnas.1419828112ISSN 0027-8424PMID 26243876PMC 4547273.
  3.  "A Flawed Elections Conspiracy Theory".
  4. ↑ Jump up to:4.0 4.1 4.2 "How the internet flips elections and alters our thoughts — Robert Epstein — Aeon Essays".
  5. ↑ Jump up to:5.0 5.1 5.2 Silver, Vernon; Stone, Brad (August 6, 2015). "Google’s $6 Billion Miscalculation on the EU". Retrieved 2015-08-25.
  6.  Hern, Alex (10 June 2016). "Google Manipulating Search In Favor Of Hillary Clinton?". Retrieved 10 June 2016.
  7.  Richardson, Valerie (9 June 2016). "Google accused of burying negative Hillary Clinton stories"The Washington Times. Retrieved 10 June 2016.
  8.  TAKALA, RUDY (2016-06-11). "Google denies manipulating search results to favor Hillary Clinton".

External links

The search engine manipulation effect (SEME) and its possible impact on the outcomes of elections

Robert Epstein This email address is being protected from spambots. You need JavaScript enabled to view it. and Ronald E. RobertsonAuthors Info & Affiliations
Edited by Jacob N. Shapiro, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ, and accepted by the Editorial Board July 8, 2015 (received for review October 16, 2014)
August 4, 2015
112 (33) E4512-E4521

The search engine manipulation effect (SEME) and its possible impact on the outcomes of elections | PNAS

Significance

We present evidence from five experiments in two countries suggesting the power and robustness of the search engine manipulation effect (SEME). Specifically, we show that (i) biased search rankings can shift the voting preferences of undecided voters by 20% or more, (ii) the shift can be much higher in some demographic groups, and (iii) such rankings can be masked so that people show no awareness of the manipulation. Knowing the proportion of undecided voters in a population who have Internet access, along with the proportion of those voters who can be influenced using SEME, allows one to calculate the win margin below which SEME might be able to determine an election outcome.

Abstract

Internet search rankings have a significant impact on consumer choices, mainly because users trust and choose higher-ranked results more than lower-ranked results. Given the apparent power of search rankings, we asked whether they could be manipulated to alter the preferences of undecided voters in democratic elections. Here we report the results of five relevant double-blind, randomized controlled experiments, using a total of 4,556 undecided voters representing diverse demographic characteristics of the voting populations of the United States and India. The fifth experiment is especially notable in that it was conducted with eligible voters throughout India in the midst of India’s 2014 Lok Sabha elections just before the final votes were cast. The results of these experiments demonstrate that (i) biased search rankings can shift the voting preferences of undecided voters by 20% or more, (ii) the shift can be much higher in some demographic groups, and (iii) search ranking bias can be masked so that people show no awareness of the manipulation. We call this type of influence, which might be applicable to a variety of attitudes and beliefs, the search engine manipulation effect. Given that many elections are won by small margins, our results suggest that a search engine company has the power to influence the results of a substantial number of elections with impunity. The impact of such manipulations would be especially large in countries dominated by a single search engine company.
Recent research has demonstrated that the rankings of search results provided by search engine companies have a dramatic impact on consumer attitudes, preferences, and behavior (1 –12); this is presumably why North American companies now spend more than 20 billion US dollars annually on efforts to place results at the top of rankings (1314). Studies using eye-tracking technology have shown that people generally scan search engine results in the order in which the results appear and then fixate on the results that rank highest, even when lower-ranked results are more relevant to their search (1 –5). Higher-ranked links also draw more clicks, and consequently people spend more time on Web pages associated with higher-ranked search results (1 –9). A recent analysis of ∼300 million clicks on one search engine found that 91.5% of those clicks were on the first page of search results, with 32.5% on the first result and 17.6% on the second (7). The study also reported that the bottom item on the first page of results drew 140% more clicks than the first item on the second page (7). These phenomena occur apparently because people trust search engine companies to assign higher ranks to the results best suited to their needs (1 –411), even though users generally have no idea how results get ranked (15).
Why do search rankings elicit such consistent browsing behavior? Part of the answer lies in the basic design of a search engine results page: the list. For more than a century, research has shown that an item’s position on a list has a powerful and persuasive impact on subjects’ recollection and evaluation of that item (16 –18). Specific order effects, such as primacy and recency, show that the first and last items presented on a list, respectively, are more likely to be recalled than items in the middle (1617).
Primacy effects in particular have been shown to have a favorable influence on the formation of attitudes and beliefs (18 –20), enhance perceptions of corporate performance (21), improve ratings of items on a survey (22 –24), and increase purchasing behavior (25). More troubling, however, is the finding that primacy effects have a significant impact on voting behavior, resulting in more votes for the candidate whose name is listed first on a ballot (26 –32). In one recent experimental study, primacy accounted for a 15% gain in votes for the candidate listed first (30). Although primacy effects have been shown to extend to hyperlink clicking behavior in online environments (33 –35), no study that we are aware of has yet examined whether the deliberate manipulation of search engine rankings can be leveraged as a form of persuasive technology in elections. Given the power of order effects and the impact that search rankings have on consumer attitudes and behavior, we asked whether the deliberate manipulation of search rankings pertinent to candidates in political elections could alter the attitudes, beliefs, and behavior of undecided voters.
It is already well established that biased media sources such as newspapers (36 –38), political polls (39), and television (40) sway voters (4142). A 2007 study by DellaVigna and Kaplan found, for example, that whenever the conservative-leaning Fox television network moved into a new market in the United States, conservative votes increased, a phenomenon they labeled the Fox News Effect (40). These researchers estimated that biased coverage by Fox News was sufficient to shift 10,757 votes in Florida during the 2000 US Presidential election: more than enough to flip the deciding state in the election, which was carried by the Republican presidential candidate by only 537 votes. The Fox News Effect was also found to be smaller in television markets that were more competitive.
We believe, however, that the impact of biased search rankings on voter preferences is potentially much greater than the influence of traditional media sources (43), where parties compete in an open marketplace for voter allegiance. Search rankings are controlled in most countries today by a single company. If, with or without intervention by company employees, the algorithm that ranked election-related information favored one candidate over another, competing candidates would have no way of compensating for the bias. It would be as if Fox News were the only television network in the country. Biased search rankings would, in effect, be an entirely new type of social influence, and it would be occurring on an unprecedented scale. Massive experiments conducted recently by social media giant Facebook have already introduced other unprecedented types of influence made possible by the Internet. Notably, an experiment reported recently suggested that flashing “VOTE” ads to 61 million Facebook users caused more than 340,000 people to vote that day who otherwise would not have done so (44). Zittrain has pointed out that if Facebook executives chose to prompt only those people who favored a particular candidate or party, they could easily flip an election in favor of that candidate, performing a kind of “digital gerrymandering” (45).
We evaluated the potential impact of biased search rankings on voter preferences in a series of experiments with the same general design. Subjects were asked for their opinions and voting preferences both before and after they were allowed to conduct research on candidates using a mock search engine we had created for this purpose. Subjects were randomly assigned to groups in which the search results they were shown were biased in favor of one candidate or another, or, in a control condition, in favor of neither candidate. Would biased search results change the opinions and voting preferences of undecided voters, and, if so, by how much? Would some demographic groups be more vulnerable to such a manipulation? Would people be aware that they were viewing biased rankings? Finally, what impact would familiarity with the candidates have on the manipulation?

Study 1: Three Experiments in San Diego, CA

To determine the potential for voter manipulation using biased search rankings, we initially conducted three laboratory-based experiments in the United States, each using a double-blind control group design with random assignment. For each of the experiments, we recruited 102 eligible voters through newspaper and online advertisements, as well through notices in senior recreation centers, in the San Diego, CA, area.* The advertisements offered USD$25 for each subject’s participation, and subjects were prescreened in an attempt to match diverse demographic characteristics of the US voting population (46).
Each of the three experiments used 30 actual search results and corresponding Web pages relating to the 2010 election to determine the prime minister of Australia. The candidates were Tony Abbott and Julia Gillard, and the order in which their names were presented was counterbalanced in all conditions. This election was used to minimize possible preexisting biases by US study participants and thus to try to guarantee that our subjects would be truly “undecided.” In each experiment, subjects were randomly assigned to one of three groups: (i) rankings favoring Gillard (which means that higher-ranked search results linked to Web pages that portrayed Gillard as the better candidate), (ii) rankings favoring Abbott, or (iii) rankings favoring neither (Fig. 1 A–C). The order of these rankings was determined based on ratings of Web pages provided by three independent observers. Neither the subjects nor the research assistants who supervised them knew either the hypothesis of the experiment or the groups to which subjects were assigned.
Fig. 1.
Search rankings for the three experiments in study 1. (A) For subjects in group 1 of experiment 1, 30 search results that linked to 30 corresponding Web pages were ranked in a fixed order that favored candidate Julia Gillard, as follows: those favoring Gillard (from highest to lowest rated pages), then those favoring neither candidate, then those favoring Abbott (from lowest to highest rated pages). (B) For subjects in group 2 of experiment 1, the search results were displayed in precisely the opposite order so that they favored the opposing candidate, Tony Abbott. (C) For subjects in group 3 of experiment 1 (the control group), the ranking favored neither candidate. (D) For subjects in groups 1 and 2 of experiment 2, the rankings bias was masked slightly by swapping results that had originally appeared in positions 4 and 27. Thus, on the first page of search results, five of the six results—all but the one in the fourth position—favored one candidate. (E) For subjects in groups 1 and 2 of experiment 3, a more aggressive mask was used by swapping results that had originally appeared in positions 3 and 28.
OPEN IN VIEWER
Initially, subjects read brief biographies of the candidates and rated them on 10-point Likert scales with respect to their overall impression of each candidate, how much they trusted each candidate, and how much they liked each candidate. They were also asked how likely they would be to vote for one candidate or the other on an 11-point scale ranging from −5 to +5, as well as to indicate which of the two candidates they would vote for if the election were held that day.
The subjects then spent up to 15 min gathering more information about the candidates using a mock search engine we had created (called Kadoodle), which gave subjects access to five pages of search results with six results per page. As is usual with search engines, subjects could click on any search result to view the corresponding Web page, or they could click on numbers at the bottom of each results page to view other results pages. The same search results and Web pages were used for all subjects in each experiment; only the order of the search results was varied (Fig. 1). Subjects had the option to end the search whenever they felt they had acquired sufficient information to make a sound decision. At the conclusion of the search, subjects rated the candidates again. When their ratings were complete, subjects were asked (on their computer screens) whether anything about the search rankings they had viewed “bothered” them; they were then given an opportunity to write at length about what, if anything, had bothered them. We did not ask specifically whether the search rankings appeared to be “biased” to avoid false positives typically generated by leading or suggestive questions (47).
Regarding the ethics of our study, our manipulation could have no impact on a past election, and we were also not concerned that it could affect the outcome of future elections, because the number of subjects we recruited was small and, to our knowledge, included no Australian voters. Moreover, our study was designed so that it did not favor any one candidate, so there was no overall bias. The study presented no more than minimal risk to subjects and was approved by the Institutional Review Board (IRB) of the American Institute for Behavioral Research and Technology (AIBRT). Informed consent was obtained from all subjects.
In aggregate for the first three experiments in San Diego, CA, the demographic characteristics of our subjects (mean age, 42.5 y; SD = 18.1 y; range, 18–95 y) did not differ from characteristics of the US voting population by more than the following margins: 6.4% within any category of the age or sex measures; 14.1% within any category of the race measure; 18.7% within any category of the income or education measures; and 21.1% within any category of the employment status measure (Table S1). Subjects’ political inclinations were fairly balanced, with 20.3% identifying themselves as conservative, 28.8% as moderate, 22.5% as liberal, and 28.4% as indifferent. Political party affiliation, however, was less balanced, with 21.6% identifying as Republican, 19.6% as Independent, 44.8% as Democrat, 6.2% as Libertarian, and 7.8% as other. In aggregate, subjects reported conducting an average of 7.9 searches (SD = 17.5) per day using search engines, and 52.3% reported having conducted searches to learn about political candidates. They also reported having little or no familiarity with the candidates (mean familiarity on a scale of 1–10, 1.4; SD = 0.99). On average, subjects in the first three experiments spent 635.9 s (SD = 307.0) using our mock search engine.
Table S1.
Demographics for studies 1 and 2
*
P < 0.05; **P < 0.01; and ***P < 0.001.
Census numbers are in hundred thousands.
For census data, “No” includes “unemployed” and “not in labor force.”
OPEN IN VIEWER
As expected, higher search rankings drew more clicks, and the pattern of clicks for the first three experiments correlated strongly with the pattern found in a recent analysis of ∼300 million clicks [r(13) = 0.90, P < 0.001; Kolmogorov–Smirnov test of differences in distributions: D = 0.033, P = 0.31; Fig. 2] (7). In addition, subjects spent more time on Web pages associated with higher-ranked results (Fig. 2), as well as substantially more time on earlier search pages (Fig. 3).
Fig. 2.
Clicks on search results and time allocated to Web pages as a function of search result rank, aggregated across the three experiments in study 1. Subjects spent less time on Web pages corresponding to lower-ranked search results (blue curve) and were less likely to click on lower-ranked results (red curve). This pattern is found routinely in studies of Internet search engine use (1 –12).
OPEN IN VIEWER
Fig. 3.
Amount of time, aggregated across the three experiments in study 1, that subjects spent on each of the five search pages. Subjects spent most of their time on the first search page, a common finding in Internet search engine research (1 –12).
OPEN IN VIEWER
In experiment 1, we found no significant differences among the three groups with respect to subjects’ ratings of the candidates before Web research (Table S2). Following the Web research, all candidate ratings in the bias groups shifted in the predicted directions compared with candidate ratings in the control group (Table 1).
Table 1.
Postsearch shifts in voting preferences for study 1
*
P < 0.05, **P < 0.01, and ***P < 0.001: Mann–Whitney u tests were conducted between the control group and each of the bias groups.
OPEN IN VIEWER
Table S2.
Voting preferences by group for study 1
*
P < 0.05; **P < 0.01; and ***P < 0.001: Kruskal–Wallis tests were conducted between all three groups, and Mann–Whitney u tests were conducted between groups 1 and 2. Preferences were measured for each candidate separately on 10-point Likert scales.
OPEN IN VIEWER
Before Web research, we found no significant differences among the three groups with respect to the proportions of people who said that they would vote for one candidate or the other if the election were held today (Table 2). Following Web research, significant differences emerged among the three groups for this measure (Table 2), and the number of subjects who said they would vote for the favored candidate in the two bias groups combined increased by 48.4% (95% CI, 30.8–66.0%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.01).
Table 2.
Comparison of voting proportions before and after Web research by group for studies 1 and 2
McNemar's test was conducted to assess VMP significance. VMP, percent increase in subjects in the bias groups combined who said that they would vote for the favored candidate.
*
P < 0.05; **P < 0.01; and ***P < 0.001: Pearson χ2 tests were conducted among all three groups.
OPEN IN VIEWER
We define the latter percentage as vote manipulation power (VMP). Thus, before the Web search, if a total of � subjects in the bias groups said they would vote for the target candidate, and if, following the Web search, a total of �' subjects in the bias groups said they would vote for the target candidate, VMP = (�′−�)/�. The VMP is, we believe, the key measure that an administrator would want to know if he or she were trying to manipulate an election using SEME.
Using a more sensitive measure than forced binary choice, we also asked subjects to estimate the likelihood, on an 11-point scale from −5 to +5, that they would vote for one candidate or the other if the election were held today. Before Web research, we found no significant differences among the three groups with respect to the likelihood of voting for one candidate or the other [Kruskal–Wallis (K–W) test: χ2(2) = 1.384, P = 0.501]. Following Web research, the likelihood of voting for either candidate in the bias groups diverged from their initial scale values by 3.71 points in the predicted directions [Mann–Whitney (M–W) test: u = 300.5, P < 0.01]. Notably, 75% of subjects in the bias groups showed no awareness of the manipulation. We counted subjects as showing awareness of the manipulation if (i) they had clicked on the box indicating that something bothered them about the rankings and (ii) we found specific terms or phrases in their open-ended comments suggesting that they were aware of bias in the rankings (SI Text).
In experiment 2, we sought to determine whether the proportion of subjects who were unaware of the manipulation could be increased with voter preferences still shifting in the predicted directions. We accomplished this by masking our manipulation to some extent. Specifically, the search result that had appeared in the fourth position on the first page of the search results favoring Abbott in experiment 1 was swapped with the corresponding search result favoring Gillard (Fig. 1D). Before Web research, we found no significant differences among the three groups with respect to subjects’ ratings of the candidates (Table S2). Following the Web research, all candidate ratings in the bias groups shifted in the predicted directions compared with candidate ratings in the control group (Table 1).
Before Web research, we found no significant differences among the three groups with respect to voting proportions (Table 2). Following Web research, significant differences emerged among the three groups for this measure (Table 2), and the VMP was 63.3% (95% CI, 46.1–80.6%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001).
For the more sensitive measure (the 11-point scale), we found no significant differences among the three groups with respect to the likelihood of voting for one candidate or the other before Web research [K-W test: χ2(2) = 0.888, P = 0.642]. Following Web research, the likelihood of voting for either candidate in the bias groups diverged from their initial scale values by 4.44 points in the predicted directions (M-W test: u = 237.5, P < 0.001). In addition, the proportion of people who showed no awareness of the manipulation increased from 75% in experiment 1 to 85% in experiment 2, although the difference between these percentages was not significant (χ2 = 2.264, P = 0.07).
In experiment 3, we sought to further increase the proportion of subjects who were unaware of the manipulation by using a more aggressive mask. Specifically, the search result that had appeared in the third position on the first page of the search results favoring Abbott in experiment 1 was swapped with the corresponding search result favoring Gillard (Fig. 1E). This mask is a more aggressive one because higher ranked results are viewed more and taken more seriously by people conducting searches (1 –12).
Before Web research, we found no significant differences among the three groups with respect to subjects’ ratings of candidates (Table S2). Following the Web research, all candidate ratings in the bias groups shifted in the predicted directions compared with candidate ratings in the control group (Table 1).
Before Web research, we found no significant differences among the three groups with respect to voting proportions (Table 2). Following Web research, significant differences did not emerge among the three groups for this measure (Table 2); the VMP, however, was 36.7% (95% CI, 19.4–53.9%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.05).
For the more sensitive measure (the 11-point scale), we found no significant differences among the three groups with respect to the likelihood of voting for one candidate or the other before Web research [K-W test: χ2(2) = 0.624, P = 0.732]. Following Web research, the likelihood of voting for either candidate in the bias groups diverged from their initial scale values by 2.62 points in the predicted directions (M-W test: u = 297.0, P < 0.001). Notably, in experiment 3, no subjects showed awareness of the rankings bias, and the difference between the proportions of subjects who appeared to be unaware of the manipulations in experiments 1 and 3 was significant (χ2 = 19.429, P < 0.001).
Although the findings from these first three experiments were robust, the use of small samples from one US city limited their generalizability and might even have exaggerated the effect size (48).

Study 2: Large-Scale National Online Replication of Experiment 3

To better assess the generalizability of SEME to the US population at large, we used a diverse national sample of 2,100 individuals from all 50 US states (Table S1), recruited using Amazon’s Mechanical Turk (mturk.com), an online subject pool that is now commonly used by behavioral researchers (4950). Subjects (mean age, 33.9 y; SD = 11.9 y; range, 18–81 y) were exposed to the same aggressive masking procedure we used in experiment 3 (Fig. 1E). Each subject was paid USD$1 for his or her participation.
Regarding ethical concerns, as in study 1, our manipulation could have no impact on a past election, and we were not concerned that it could affect the outcome of future elections. Moreover, our study was designed so that it did not favor any one candidate, so there was no overall bias. The study presented no more than minimal risk to subjects and was approved by AIBRT’s IRB. Informed consent was obtained from all subjects.
Subjects’ political inclinations were less balanced than those in study 1, with 19.5% of subjects identifying themselves as conservative, 24.2% as moderate, 50.2% as liberal, and 6.3% as indifferent; 16.1% of subjects identified themselves as Republican, 29.9% as Independent, 43.2% as Democrat, 8.0% as Libertarian, and 2.9% as other. Subjects reported having little or no familiarity with the candidates (mean, 1.9; SD = 1.7). As one might expect in a study using only Internet-based subjects, self-reported search engine use was higher in study 2 than in study 1 [mean searches per day, 15.3; SD = 26.3; t(529.5) = 6.9, P < 0.001], and more subjects reported having previously used a search engine to learn about political candidates (86.0%, χ2 = 204.1, P < 0.001). Subjects in study 2 also spent less time using our mock search engine [mean total time, 309.2 s; SD = 278.7; t(381.9) = −17.6, P < 0.001], but patterns of search result clicks and time spent on Web pages were similar to those we found in study 1 [clicks: r(28) = 0.98, P < 0.001; Web page time: r(28) = 0.98, P < 0.001] and to those routinely found in other studies (1 –12).
Before Web research, we found no significant differences among the three groups with respect to subjects’ ratings of the candidates (Table S3). Following the Web research, all candidate ratings in the bias groups shifted in the predicted directions compared with candidate ratings in the control group (Table 3).
Table 3.
Postsearch shifts in voting preferences for study 2
***
P < 0.001: Mann–Whitney u tests were conducted between the control group and each of the bias groups.
OPEN IN VIEWER
Table S3.
Voting preferences by group for study 2
***P < 0.001: Kruskal–Wallis tests were conducted between all three groups, and Mann–Whitney u tests were conducted between groups 1 and 2. Preferences were measured for each candidate separately on 10-point Likert scales.
OPEN IN VIEWER
Before Web research, we found no significant differences among the three groups with respect to voting proportions (Table 2). Following Web research, significant differences emerged among the three groups for this measure (Table 2), and the VMP was 37.1% (95% CI, 33.5–40.7%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001). Using poststratification and weights obtained from the 2010 US Census (46) and a 2011 study from Gallup (51), which were scaled to size for age, sex, race, and education, the VMP was 36.7% (95% CI, 33.2–40.3%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001). When weighted using the same demographics via classical regression poststratification (52) (Table S4), the VMP was 33.5% (95% CI, 30.1–37.0%, McNemar’s test, P < 0.001).
Table S4.
Treatment effect estimates for study 2 voting preferences
The presearch and postsearch columns report the estimate and variance for both treatment groups using classical regression poststratification. Data for sex, race/ethnicity, age group, and education level came from the 2010 US Census. Data on the number of people who identify their sex as “other” came from a 2011 Gallup study.
*
P < 0.05.
OPEN IN VIEWER
For the more sensitive measure (the 11-point scale), we found no significant differences among the three groups with respect to the likelihood of voting for one candidate or the other before Web research [K-W test: χ2(2) = 2.790, P = 0.248]. Following Web research, the likelihood of voting for either candidate in the bias groups diverged from their initial scale values by 3.03 points in the predicted directions (M-W test: u = 1.29 × 105P < 0.001). As one might expect of a more Internet-fluent sample, the proportion of subjects showing no awareness of the manipulation dropped to 91.4%.
The number of subjects in study 1 was too small to look at demographic differences. In study 2, we found substantial differences in how vulnerable different demographic groups were to SEME. Consistent with previous findings on the moderators of order effects (30 –32), for example, we found that subjects reporting a low familiarity with the candidates (familiarity less than 5 on a scale from 1 to 10) were more vulnerable to SEME (VMP = 38.7%; 95% CI, 34.9–42.4%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001) than were subjects who reported high familiarity with the candidates (VMP = 19.3%; 95% CI, 9.1–29.5%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.05), and this difference was significant (χ2 = 8.417, P < 0.01).
We found substantial differences in vulnerability to SEME among a number of different demographic groups (SI Text). Although the groups we examined were overlapping and somewhat arbitrary, if one were manipulating an election, information about such differences would have enormous practical value. For example, we found that self-labeled Republicans were more vulnerable to SEME (VMP = 54.4%; 95% CI, 45.2–63.5%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001) than were self-labeled Democrats (VMP = 37.7%; 95% CI, 32.3–43.1%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001) and that self-labeled divorcees were more vulnerable (VMP = 46.7%; 95% CI, 32.1–61.2%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001) than were self-labeled married subjects (VMP = 32.4%; 95% CI, 26.8–38.1%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001). Among the most vulnerable groups we identified were Moderate Republicans (VMP = 80.0%; 95% CI, 62.5–97.5%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001), whereas among the least vulnerable groups were people who reported a household income of $40,000 to $49,999 (VMP = 22.5%; 95% CI, 13.8–31.1%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001).
Notably, awareness of the manipulation not only did not nullify the effect, it seemed to enhance it, perhaps because people trust search order so much that awareness of the bias serves to confirm the superiority of the favored candidate. The VMP for people who showed no awareness of the biased search rankings (n = 1,280) was 36.3% (95% CI, 32.6–40.1%; McNemar's test, P < 0.001), whereas the VMP for people who showed awareness of the bias (n = 120) was 45.0% (95% CI, 32.4–57.6%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001).
Having now replicated the effect with a large and diverse sample of US subjects, we were concerned about the weaknesses associated with testing subjects on a somewhat abstract election (the election in Australia) that had taken place years before and in which subjects were unfamiliar with the candidates. In real elections, people are familiar with the candidates and are influenced, sometimes on a daily basis, by aggressive campaigning. Presumably, either of these two factors—familiarity and outside influence—could potentially minimize or negate the influence of biased search rankings on voter preferences. We therefore asked if SEME could be replicated with a large and diverse sample of real voters in the midst of a real election campaign.

Study 3: SEME Evaluated During the 2014 Lok Sabha Elections in India

In our fifth experiment, we sought to manipulate the voting preferences of undecided eligible voters in India during the 2014 national Lok Sabha elections there. This election was the largest democratic election in history, with more than 800 million eligible voters and more than 430 million votes ultimately cast. We accomplished this by randomly assigning undecided English-speaking voters throughout India who had not yet voted (recruited through print advertisements, online advertisements, and online subject pools) to one of three groups in which search rankings favored either Rahul Gandhi, Arvind Kejriwal, or Narendra Modi, the three major candidates in the election.§
Subjects were incentivized to participate in the study either with payments between USD$1 and USD$4 or with the promise that a donation of approximately USD$1.50 would be made to a prominent Indian charity that provides free lunches for Indian children. (At the close of the study, a donation of USD$1,457 was made to the Akshaya Patra Foundation.)
Regarding ethical concerns, because we recruited only a small number of subjects relative to the size of the Indian voting population, we were not concerned that our manipulation could affect the election’s outcome. Moreover, our study was designed so that it did not favor any one candidate, so there was no overall bias. The study presented no more than minimal risk to subjects and was approved by AIBRT’s IRB. Informed consent was obtained from all subjects.
The subjects (n = 2,150) were demographically diverse (Table S5), residing in 27 of 35 Indian states and union territories, and political leanings varied as follows: 13.3% identified themselves as politically right (conservative), 43.8% as center (moderate), 26.0% as left (liberal), and 16.9% as indifferent. In contrast to studies 1 and 2, subjects reported high familiarity with the political candidates (mean familiarity Gandhi, 7.9; SD = 2.5; mean familiarity Kejriwal, 7.7; SD = 2.5; mean familiarity Modi, 8.5; SD = 2.1). The full dataset for all five experiments is accessible at Dataset S1.
Table S5.
Demographics for study 3
OPEN IN VIEWER
Subjects reported more frequent search engine use compared with subjects in studies 1 or 2 (mean searches per day, 15.7; SD = 30.1), and 71.7% of subjects reported that they had previously used a search engine to learn about political candidates. Subjects also spent less time using our mock search engine (mean total time, 277.4 s; SD = 368.3) than did subjects in studies 1 or 2. The patterns of search result clicks and time spent on Web pages in our mock search engine was similar to the patterns we found in study 1 [clicks, r(28) = 0.96; P < 0.001; Web page time, r(28) = 0.91; P < 0.001] and study 2 [clicks, r(28) = 0.96; P < 0.001; Web page time, r(28) = 0.92; P < 0.001].
Before Web research, we found one significant difference among the three groups for a rating pertaining to Kejriwal, but none for Gandhi or Modi (Table S6). Following the Web research, most of the subjects’ ratings of the candidates shifted in the predicted directions (Table 4).
Table 4.
Postsearch shifts in voting preferences for study 3
**
P < 0.01 and ***P < 0.001: for each rating, a Kruskal–Wallis χ2 test was used to assess significance of group differences.
OPEN IN VIEWER
Table S6.
Voting Preferences by Group for Study 3
*
P < 0.05; **P < 0.01; and ***P < 0.001: Kruskal–Wallis tests were conducted between all three groups. Preferences were measured for each candidate separately on 10-point Likert scales.
OPEN IN VIEWER
Before Web research, we found no significant differences among the three groups with respect to voting proportions (Table 5). Following Web research, significant differences emerged among the three groups for this measure (Table 5), and the VMP was 10.6% (95% CI, 8.3–12.8%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001). Using poststratification and weights obtained from the 2011 India Census data on literate Indians (53)—scaled to size for age, sex, and location (grouped into state or union territory)—the VMP was 9.4% (95% CI, 8.2–10.6%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001). When weighted using the same demographics via classical regression poststratification (Table S7), the VMP was 9.5% (95% CI, 8.3–10.7%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001).
Table 5.
Comparison of voting proportions before and after Web research for study 3
Group Simulated vote before Web research χ2 Simulated vote after Web research χ2 VMP
Gandhi Kejriwal Modi Gandhi Kejriwal Modi
1 115 164 430 3.070 144 152 413 16.935** 10.6%***
2 112 183 393   113 199 376    
3 127 196 430   117 174 462    
McNemar's test was conducted to assess VMP significance. VMP, percent increase in subjects in the bias groups combined who said that they would vote for the favored candidate.
**P < 0.01; and ***P < 0.001: Pearson χ2 tests were conducted among all three groups.
OPEN IN VIEWER
Table S7.
Treatment effect estimates for study 3 voting preferences
The presearch and postsearch columns report the estimate and variance for both of the treatment groups using classical regression poststratification. Data for sex, age group, and location came from the 2011 India Census.
***P < 0.001.
OPEN IN VIEWER
To obtain a more sensitive measure of voting preference in study 3, we asked subjects to estimate the likelihood, on three separate 11-point scales from −5 to +5, that they would vote for each of the candidates if the election were held today. Before Web research, we found no significant differences among the three groups with respect to the likelihood of voting for any of the candidates (Table S6). Following Web research, significant differences emerged among the three groups with respect to the likelihood of voting for Rahul Gandhi and Arvind Kejriwal but not Narendra Modi (Table S6), and all likelihoods shifted in the predicted directions (Table 4). The proportion of subjects showing no awareness of the manipulation in experiment 5 was 99.5%.
In study 3, as in study 2, we found substantial differences in how vulnerable different demographic groups were to SEME (SI Text). Consistent with the findings of study 2 and previous findings on the moderators of order effects (30 –32), for example, we found that subjects reporting a low familiarity with the candidates (familiarity less than 5 on a scale from 1 to 10) were more vulnerable to SEME (VMP = 13.7%; 95% CI, 4.3–23.2%; McNemar’s test, P = 0.17) than were subjects who reported high familiarity with the candidates (VMP = 10.3%; 95% CI, 8.0–12.6%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001), although this difference was not significant (χ2 = 0.575, P = 0.45).
As in study 2, although the demographic groups we examined were overlapping and somewhat arbitrary, if one was manipulating an election, information about such differences would have enormous practical value. For example, we found that subjects between ages 18 and 24 were less vulnerable to SEME (VMP = 8.9%; 95% CI, 5.0–12.8%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.05) than were subjects between ages 45 and 64 (VMP = 18.9%; 95% CI, 6.3–31.5%; McNemar’s test, P = 0.10) and that self-labeled Christians were more vulnerable (VMP = 30.7%; 95% CI, 20.2–41.1%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001) than self-labeled Hindus (VMP = 8.7%; 95% CI, 6.3–11.1%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001). Among the most vulnerable groups we identified were unemployed males from Kerala (VMP = 72.7%; 95% CI, 46.4–99.0%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.05), whereas among the least vulnerable groups were female conservatives (VMP = −11.8%; 95% CI, −29.0%–5.5%; McNemar's test, P = 0.62).
A negative VMP might suggest oppositional attitudes or an underdog effect for that group (54). No negative VMPs were found in the demographic groups examined in study 2, but it is understandable that they would be found in an election in which people are highly familiar with the candidates (study 3). As a practical matter, where a search engine company has the ability to send people customized rankings and where biased search rankings are likely to produce an oppositional response with certain voters, such rankings would probably not be sent to them. Eliminating the 2.6% of our sample (n = 56) with oppositional responses, the overall VMP in this experiment increases from 10.6% to 19.8% (95% CI, 16.8–22.8%; n = 2,094; McNemar’s test: P < 0.001).
As we found in study 2, awareness of the manipulation appeared to enhance the effect rather than nullify it. The VMP for people who showed no awareness of the biased search rankings (n = 2,140) was 10.5% (95% CI, 8.3–12.7%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001), whereas the VMP for people who showed awareness of the bias (n = 10) was 33.3%.
The rankings and Web pages we used in study 3 were selected by the investigators based on our limited understanding of Indian politics and perspectives. To optimize the rankings, midway through the election process we hired a native consultant who was familiar with the issues and perspectives pertinent to undecided voters in the 2014 Lok Sabha Election. Based on the recommendations of the consultant, we made slight changes to our rankings on 30 April, 2014. In the preoptimized rankings group (n = 1,259), the VMP was 9.5% (95% CI, 6.8–12.2%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001); in the postoptimized rankings group (n = 891), the VMP increased to 12.3% (95% CI, 8.5–16.1%; McNemar’s test, P < 0.001). Eliminating the 3.1% of the subjects in the postoptimization sample with oppositional responses (n = 28), the VMP increased to 24.5% (95% CI, 19.3–29.8%; n = 863).

Discussion

Elections are often won by small vote margins. Fifty percent of US presidential elections were won by vote margins under 7.6%, and 25% of US senatorial elections in 2012 were won by vote margins under 6.0% (5556). In close elections, undecided voters can make all of the difference, which is why enormous resources are often focused on those voters in the days before the election (5758). Because search rankings biased toward one candidate can apparently sway the voting preferences of undecided voters without their awareness and, at least under some circumstances, without any possible competition from opposing candidates, SEME appears to be an especially powerful tool for manipulating elections. The Australian election used in studies 1 and 2 was won by a margin of only 0.24% and perhaps could easily have been turned by such a manipulation. The Fox News Effect, which is small compared with SEME, is believed to have shifted between 0.4% and 0.7% of votes to conservative candidates: more than enough, according to the researchers, to have had a “decisive” effect on a number of close elections in 2000 (40).
Political scientists have identified two of the most common methods political candidates use to try to win elections. The core voter model describes a strategy in which resources are devoted to mobilizing supporters to vote (59). As noted earlier, Zittrain recently pointed out that a company such as Facebook could mobilize core voters to vote on election day by sending “get-out-and-vote” messages en masse to supporters of only one candidate. Such a manipulation could be used undetectably to flip an election in what might be considered a sort of digital gerrymandering (4445). In contrast, the swing voter model describes a strategy in which candidates target their resources toward persuasion—attempting to change the voting preferences of undecided voters (60). SEME is an ideal method for influencing such voters.
Although relatively few voters have actively sought political information about candidates in the past (61), the ease of obtaining information over the Internet appears to be changing that: 73% of online adults used the Internet for campaign-related purposes during the 2010 US midterm elections (61), and 55% of all registered voters went online to watch videos related to the 2012 US election campaign (62). Moreover, 84% of registered voters in the United States were Internet users in 2012 (62). In our nationwide study in the United States (study 2), 86.0% of our subjects reported having used search engines to get information about candidates. Meanwhile, the number of people worldwide with Internet access is increasing rapidly, predicted to increase to nearly 4 billion by 2018 (63). By 2018, Internet access in India is expected to rise from the 213 million users who had access in 2013 to 526 million (63). Worldwide, it is reasonable to conjecture that both proportions will increase substantially in future years; that is, more people will have Internet access, and more people will obtain information about candidates from the Internet. In the context of the experiments we have presented, this suggests that whatever the effect sizes we have observed now, they will likely be larger in the future.
The power of SEME to affect elections in a two-person race can be roughly estimated by making a small number of fairly conservative assumptions. Where � is the proportion of voters with Internet access, � is the proportion of those voters who are undecided, and VMP, as noted above, is the proportion of those undecided voters who can be swayed by SEME, �—the maximum win margin controllable by SEME—can be estimated by the following formula: �=�∗�∗���.
In a three-person race, � will vary between 75% and 100% of its value in a two-person race, depending on how the votes are distributed between the two losing candidates. (Derivations of formulas in the two-candidate and three-candidate cases are available in SI Text.) In both cases, the size of the population is irrelevant.
Knowing the values for � and � for a given election, along with the projected win margin, the minimum VMP needed to put one candidate ahead can be calculated (Table S8). In theory, continuous online polling would allow search rankings to be optimized continuously to increase the value of VMP until, in some instances, it could conceivably guarantee an election’s outcome, much as “conversion” and “click-through” rates are now optimized continuously in Internet marketing (64).
Table S8.
Minimum VMP levels needed to impact two-person races with various projected win margins and proportions of undecided Internet voters
OPEN IN VIEWER
For example, if (i) 80% of eligible voters had Internet access, (ii) 10% of those individuals were undecided at some point, and (iii) SEME could be used to increase the number of people in the undecided group who were inclined to vote for the target candidate by 25%, that would be enough to control the outcome of an election in which the expected win margin was as high as 2%. If SEME were applied strategically and repeatedly over a period of weeks or months to increase the VMP, and if, in some locales and situations, � and � were larger than in the example given, the controllable win margin would be larger. That possibility notwithstanding, because nearly 25% of national elections worldwide are typically won by margins under 3%, SEME could conceivably impact a substantial number of elections today even with fairly low values of �, �, and VMP.
Given our procedures, however, we cannot rule out the possibility that SEME produces only a transient effect, which would limit its value in election manipulation. Laboratory manipulations of preferences and attitudes often impact subjects for only a short time, sometimes just hours (65). That said, if search rankings were being manipulated with the intent of altering the outcome of a real election, people would presumably be exposed to biased rankings repeatedly over a period of weeks or months. We produced substantial changes not only in voting preferences but in multiple ratings of attitudes toward candidates given just one exposure to search rankings linking to Web pages favoring one candidate, with average search times in the 277- to 635-s range. Given hundreds or thousands of exposures of this sort, we speculate not only that the resulting attitudes and preferences would be stable, but that they would become stronger over time, much as brand preferences become stronger when advertisements are presented repeatedly (66).
Our results also suggest that it is a relatively simple matter to mask the bias in search rankings so that it is undetectable to virtually every user. In experiment 3, using only a simple mask, none of our subjects appeared to be aware that they were seeing biased rankings, and in our India study, only 0.5% of our subjects appeared to notice the bias. When people are subjected to forms of influence they can identify—in campaigns, that means speeches, billboards, television commercials, and so on—they can defend themselves fairly easily if they have opposing views. Invisible sources of influence can be harder to defend against (67 –69), and for people who are impressionable, invisible sources of influence not only persuade, they also leave people feeling that they made up their own minds—that no external force was applied (7071). Influence is sometimes undetectable because key stimuli act subliminally (72 –74), but search results and Web pages are easy to perceive; it is the pattern of rankings that people cannot see. This invisibility makes SEME especially dangerous as a means of control, not just of voting behavior but perhaps of a wide variety of attitudes, beliefs, and behavior. Ironically, and consistent with the findings of other researchers, we found that even those subjects who showed awareness of the biased rankings were still impacted by them in the predicted directions (75).
One weakness in our studies was the manner in which we chose to determine whether subjects were aware of bias in the search rankings. As noted, to not generate false-positive responses, we avoided asking leading questions that referred specifically to bias; rather, we asked a rather vague question about whether anything had bothered subjects about the search rankings, and we then gave subjects an opportunity to type out the details of their concerns. In so doing, we probably underestimated the number of detections (47), and this is a matter that should be studied further. That said, because people who showed awareness of the bias were still vulnerable to our manipulation, people who use SEME to manipulate real elections might not be concerned about detection, except, perhaps, by regulators.
Could regulators in fact detect SEME? Theoretically, by rating pages and monitoring search rankings on an ongoing basis, search ranking bias related to elections might be possible to identify and track; as a practical matter, however, we believe that biased rankings would be impossible or nearly impossible for regulators to detect. The results of studies 2 and 3 suggest that vulnerability to SEME can vary dramatically from one demographic group to another. It follows that if one were using biased search rankings to manipulate a real election, one would focus on the most vulnerable demographic groups. Indeed, if one had access to detailed online profiles of millions of individuals, which search engine companies do (76 –78), one would presumably be able to identify those voters who appeared to be undecided and impressionable and focus one’s efforts on those individuals only—a strategy that has long been standard in political campaigns (79 –84) and continues to remain important today (85). With search engine companies becoming increasingly adept at sending users customized search rankings (76 –7886 –88), it seems likely that only customized rankings would be used to influence elections, thus making it difficult or impossible for regulators to detect a manipulation. Rankings that appear to be unbiased on the regulators’ screens might be highly biased on the screens of select individuals.
Even if a statistical analysis did show that rankings consistently favored one candidate over another, those rankings could always be attributed to algorithm-guided dynamics driven by market forces—so-called “organic” forces (89)—rather than by deliberate manipulation by search engine company employees. This possibility suggests yet another potential danger of SEME. What if election-related search results are indeed being left to the vagaries of market forces? Do such forces end up pushing some candidates to the top of search rankings? If so, it seems likely that those high rankings are cultivating additional supporters for those candidates in a kind of digital bandwagon effect. In other words, for several years now and with greater impact each year (as more people get election-related information through the Internet), SEME has perhaps already been affecting the outcomes of close elections. To put this another way, without human intention or direction, algorithms have perhaps been having a say in selecting our leaders.
Because search rankings are based, at least in part, on the popularity of Web sites (90), it is likely that voter preferences impact those rankings to some extent. Given our findings that search rankings can in turn affect voter preferences, these phenomena might interact synergistically, causing a substantial increase in support for one candidate at some point even when the effects of the individual phenomena are small.||
Our studies produced a wide range of VMPs. In a real election, what proportion of undecided voters could actually be shifted using SEME? Our first two studies, which relied on a campaign and candidates that were unfamiliar to our subjects, produced overall VMPs in the range 36.7–63.3%, with demographic shifts occurring with VMPs as high as 80.0%. Our third study, with real voters in the midst of a real election, produced, overall, a lower VMP: just 10.6%, with optimizing our rankings raising the VMP to 12.3% and with the elimination of a small number of oppositional subjects raising the VMP to 24.5%, which is the value we would presumably have found if our search rankings had been optimized from the start and if we had advance knowledge about oppositional groups. In the third study, VMPs in some demographic groups were as high as 72.7%. If a search engine company optimized rankings continuously and sent customized rankings only to vulnerable undecided voters, there is no telling how high the VMP could be pushed, but it would almost certainly be higher than our modest efforts could achieve. Our investigation suggests that with optimized, targeted rankings, a VMP of at least 20% should be relatively easy to achieve in real elections. Even if only 60% of a population had Internet access and only 10% of voters were undecided, that would still allow control of elections with win margins up to 1.2%—five times greater than the win margin in the 2010 race between Gillard and Abbott in Australia.

Conclusions

Given that search engine companies are currently unregulated, our results could be viewed as a cause for concern, suggesting that such companies could affect—and perhaps are already affecting—the outcomes of close elections worldwide. Restricting search ranking manipulations to voters who have been identified as undecided while also donating money to favored candidates would be an especially subtle, effective, and efficient way of wielding influence.
Although voters are subjected to a wide variety of influences during political campaigns, we believe that the manipulation of search rankings might exert a disproportionately large influence over voters for four reasons:
First, as we noted, the process by which search rankings affect voter preferences might interact synergistically with the process by which voter preferences affect search rankings, thus creating a sort of digital bandwagon effect that magnifies the potential impact of even minor search ranking manipulations.
Second, campaign influence is usually explicit, but search ranking manipulations are not. Such manipulations are difficult to detect, and most people are relatively powerless when trying to resist sources of influence they cannot see (66 –68). Of greater concern in the present context, when people are unaware they are being manipulated, they tend to believe they have adopted their new thinking voluntarily (6970).
Third, candidates normally have equal access to voters, but this need not be the case with search engine manipulations. Because the majority of people in most democracies use a search engine provided by just one company, if that company chose to manipulate rankings to favor particular candidates or parties, opponents would have no way to counteract those manipulations. Perhaps worse still, if that company left election-related search rankings to market forces, the search algorithm itself might determine the outcomes of many close elections.
Finally, with the attention of voters shifting rapidly toward the Internet and away from traditional sources of information (126162), the potential impact of search engine rankings on voter preferences will inevitably grow over time, as will the influence of people who have the power to control such rankings.
We conjecture, therefore, that unregulated election-related search rankings could pose a significant threat to the democratic system of government.

Materials and Methods

We used 102 subjects in each of experiments 1–3 to give us an equal number of subjects in all three groups and both counterbalancing conditions of the experiments.
Nonparametric statistical tests such as the Mann–Whitney u and the Kruskal–Wallis H are used throughout the present report because Likert scale scores, which were used in each of the studies, are ordinal.
In study 3, the procedure was identical to that of studies 1 and 2; only the Web pages and search results were different: that is, Web pages and search results were pertinent to the three leading candidates in the 2014 Lok Sabha general elections. The questions we asked subjects were also adjusted for a three-person race.
Fig. S1.
A possible synergistic relationship between the impact that search rankings have on voter preferences and the impact that voter preferences have on search rankings. The lower curves (red and green) show slow increases that might occur if each of the processes acted alone over the course of a year (365 iterations of the model). The upper curve (blue) shows the result of a possible synergy between these two processes using the same parameters that generated the two lower curves. The curves are generated by an iterative model using equations of the general form Vn+1 = Vn + r[Rn × (1 − Vn)] + r[On × (1 – Vn)], where V is voter preference for one candidate, R is the impact of voter preferences on search rankings, O is the impact (randomized with each iteration) of other influences on voter preferences, and r is a rate-of-change factor. Because a change in voter preference alters the proportion of votes available, its value in the model cannot exceed 1.0.
OPEN IN VIEWER

SI Text

Demographic Differences in VMP.

In study 2, we found substantial differences in how vulnerable different demographic groups were to SEME. Although the groups we examined are somewhat arbitrary, overlapping, and by no means definitive, they do establish a range of vulnerability to SEME. Ten groups (n ≥ 50) that appeared to be highly vulnerable in study 2, as indicated by their VMP scores, were, in order from highest to lowest, as follows:
i)
Moderate Republicans (80.0%; 95% CI, 62.5–97.5%)
ii)
People from North Carolina (66.7%; 95% CI, 42.8–90.5%)
iii)
Moderate Libertarians (73.3%; 95% CI, 51–95.7%)
iv)
Male Republicans (66.1%; 95% CI, 54–78.2%)
v)
Female conservatives age 30 and over (67.7%; 95% CI, 52.5–82.7%)
vi)
People from Virginia (60.0%; 95% CI, 38.5–81.5%)
vii)
People earning between $15,000 and $19,999 (60.0%; 95% CI, 42.5–77.5%)
viii)
Hispanics (59.4%; 95% CI, 42.4–76.4%)
ix)
Independents with no political leaning (58.3%; 95% CI, 38.6–78.1%)
x)
Female conservatives (54.7%; 95% CI, 41.3–68.1%)
Ten groups that appeared to show little vulnerability to SEME, as indicated by their VMP scores, were, in order from highest to lowest, as follows:
i)
People from California (24.1%; 95% CI, 15.1–33.1%)
ii)
Moderate independents (24.0%; 95% CI, 15.4–32.5%)
iii)
Liberal independents (23.4%; 95% CI, 13.1–33.8%)
iv)
People from Texas (22.9%; 95% CI, 11–34.8%)
v)
Liberal Libertarians (22.7%; 95% CI, 5.2–40.2%)
vi)
People earning between $40,000 and $49,999 (22.5%; 95% CI, 13.8–31.1%)
vii)
Female independents (22.0%; 95% CI, 13.5–30.5%)
viii)
Male moderates age 30 and over (19.3%; 95% CI, 9.1–29.5%)
ix)
Female independent moderates (17.9%; 95% CI, 13.5–30.5%)
x)
People with an uncommon political party (15.0%; 95% CI, −0.6% to 30.6%)
In study 3, as in study 2, we found substantial differences in how vulnerable different demographic groups were to SEME. Although the groups we examined are somewhat arbitrary, overlapping, and by no means definitive, they do establish a range of vulnerability to SEME. Ten groups (n ≥ 50) that appeared to be highly vulnerable in study 3, as indicated by their VMP scores, were, in order from highest to lowest, as follows:
i)
Unemployed males from Kerala (72.7%; 95% CI, 46.4–99.1%)
ii)
Unemployed Christians (68.8%; 95% CI, 46.0–91.5%)
iii)
Unemployed moderate males (50.0%; 95% CI, 33.2–66.8%)
iv)
Moderate Christian males (47.6%; 95% CI, 26.3–69.0%)
v)
Christian moderates (42.9%; 95% CI, 26.5–59.3%)
vi)
Males from Kerala (40.4%; 95% CI, 26.4–54.5%)
vii)
Unemployed moderates (33.3%; 95% CI, 22.0–44.7%)
viii)
Male Christians (32.7%; 95% CI, 19.9–45.4%)
ix)
People from Kerala (32.4%; 95% CI, 21.8–43.1%)
x)
Unemployed females with no political ideology (31.6%; 95% CI, 10.7–52.5%)
Ten groups that appeared to show little vulnerability to SEME, as indicated by their VMP scores, were, in order from highest to lowest, as follows:
i)
People from Tamil Nadu with no political ideology (0.0%; 95% CI, −0.01%–0.04%)
ii)
Employed females with no political ideology (0.0%; 95% CI, −0.01%–0.06%)
iii)
People earning between Rs 10,000 and Rs 29,999 (−3.2%; 95% CI, −7.6%–1.3%)
iv)
Married people who are separated (−3.3%; 95% CI, −10.0%–3.3%)
v)
People with a pre-university education (−4.3%; 95% CI, −10.5%–1.81%)
vi)
Unemployed liberals (−4.3%; 95% CI, −10.5%–1.81%)
vii)
Unemployed conservatives (−5.0%; 95% CI, −15.0%–5.0%)
viii)
People from Gujarat (−5.9%; 95% CI, −17.8%–6.0%)
ix)
Unemployed male liberals (−8.0%; 95% CI, −19.5%–3.5%)
x)
Female conservatives (−11.8%; 95% CI, −29.0%–5.5%)

Bias Awareness.

Subjects were counted as showing awareness of the manipulation if (i) they had clicked on a box indicating that something “bothered” them about the rankings and (ii) we found specific terms or phrases in their open-ended comments suggesting that they were aware of bias in the rankings, such as “biased,” “bias,” “leaning towards,” “leaning toward,” “leaning against,” “slanted,” “skewed,” “favorable towards,” “favorable toward,” “favorable for,” “favorable against,” “favorable results,” “favored towards,” “favored toward,” “favored for,” “favored against,” “favored results,” “favor toward,” “results favor,” “favor Modi,” “favor Kejriwal,” “favor Gandhi,” “negative toward,” “negative for,” “negative against,” “all negative,” “all positive,” “mainly negative,” “mainly positive,” “nothing positive,” “nothing negative,” “more results for,” “less results for,” “most of the articles were negative,” “most of the articles were positive,” “pro Modi,” “pro Kejriwal,” “pro Gandhi,” “Modi leaning,” “Kejriwal leaning,” “Gandhi leaning,” “pro Gillard,” “pro Abbott,” “favor Gillard,” “favor Abbott,” “Gillard leaning,” and “Abbott leaning.”

Derivation of the Formulas for Computing W, the Maximum Win Margin Controllable Through SEME, in Two- and Three- Person Races.

Two-person race.

Where �=total number of eligible voters in a population, � =proportion of � who are internet users, �=proportion of � who are undecided, �=proportion of � who areprone to vote for the target candidate, and VMP=proportion of � who can be shifted by SEME.
The number of votes that can be shifted by SEME is given by
�=�∗�∗�∗�∗VMP.
In a two-person race, the number of votes for the candidate favored by SEME when the vote is initially evenly split is
�2+�,
and the number of votes for the losing candidate is
�2−�.
The vote margin in favor of the winning candidate is therefore the larger vote minus the smaller vote, or, simply: 2�.
Therefore, the margin of voters, expressed as a proportion, that can be shifted by SEME is
2��=2∗�∗�∗�∗�∗VMP�=2∗�∗�∗�∗VMP.
Because the undecided voters in a two-person race have only two voting options, the value of � before outside influence is exercised can reasonably be assumed to be 0.5.
Therefore, � can be calculated as follows:
�=2∗�∗�∗0.5∗VMP ,
and the calculation can be simplified as follows:
�=�∗�∗VMP.
In other words, the maximum win margin controllable by SEME in a two-person race is equal to the proportion of people who can be influenced by SEME (the VMP) times the proportion of undecided Internet voters in the population. (� ∗�).

Three-person race.

Where �= total number of voters in a population, �=proportion of � who are internet users, �= proportion of � who are undecided, �= proportion of � who are prone to vote for the target candidate, and VMP= proportion of � who can be shifted by SEME.
The number of votes that can be shifted by SEME is given by
�=�∗�∗�∗�∗VMP.
In a three-person race, because the winning candidate can draw votes from either of the two losing candidates, � can vary between two extremes:
i)
At one extreme, one of the two losing candidates draws zero votes, in which case the formula for the two-person case (above) is applicable.
ii)
At the other extreme, voting preferences are initially split three ways evenly, and the winning candidate draws votes equally from the other two. This distribution will give us the lowest possible value of � in the three-person race, as follows.
The number of votes for the candidate favored by SEME will still be
�2+�.
However, because of the split, the number of votes for each of the losing candidates will now be
�2−�2.
The vote margin in favor of the winning candidate will therefore be the larger vote minus either of the smaller votes or, simply, 1.5�.
Therefore, the margin of voters, expressed as a proportion, that can be shifted by SEME is
2��=1.5∗�∗�∗�∗�∗VMP�=1.5∗�∗�∗�∗VMP.
Therefore, � can be calculated as follows:
�=1.5∗�∗�∗0.5∗VMP,
and the calculation can be simplified as follows:
�=0.75∗�∗�∗VMP.
Therefore, in a three-person race, � will vary between 75% and 100% of the �  found in the two-person case, depending on how votes are distributed between the two losing candidates; the more even the split, the smaller the controllable win margin.

Acknowledgments

We thank J. Arnett, E. Clemons, E. Fantino, S. Glenn, M. Hovell, E. Key, E. Loftus, C. McKenzie, B. Meredith, N. Metaxas, D. Moriarty, D. Peel, M. Runco, S. Stolarz-Fantino, and J. Wixted for comments; K. Robertson for image editing; V. Sharan for advice on optimizing search rankings in the India study; K. Duncan and F. Tran for assistance with data analysis; J. Hagan for technical assistance; and S. Palacios and K. Huynh for assistance in conducting the experiments in study 1. This work was supported by the American Institute for Behavioral Research and Technology, a nonpartisan, nonprofit organization.

Supporting Information

Supporting Information (PDF)
Supporting Information
pnas.1419828112.sd01.xls

References

 
1
T Joachims, et al., Evaluating the accuracy of implicit feedback from clicks and query reformulations in web search. Association for Computing Machinery Transactions on Information Systems 25, 7 (2007).
2
B Pan, et al., In Google we trust: User’s decisions on rank, position, and relevance. J Comput Mediat Commun 12, 801–823 (2007).
3
Z Guan, E Cutrell, An eye tracking study of the effect of target rank on web search. Proceedings of the Special Interest Group for Computer-Human Interaction Conference on Human Factors in Computing Systems (ACM, New York), pp 417–420. (2007).
4
L Lorigo, et al., Eye tracking and online search: Lessons learned and challenges ahead. J Am Soc Inf Sci Technol 59, 1041–1052 (2008).
5
LA Granka, T Joachim, G Gay, Eye-tracking analysis of user behavior in www search. Proceedings of the 27th Annual International Association for Computing Machinery Special Interest Group on Information Retrieval Conference on Research and Development in Information Retrieval (ACM, New York, NY), pp 478–479. (2004).
6
E Agichtein, E Brill, S Dumais, R Ragno, Learning user interaction models for predicting web search result preferences. Proceedings of the 29th Annual International Association for Computing Machinery Special Interest Group on Information Retrieval Conference on Research and Development in Information Retrieval (ACM, New York, NY), pp 3–10. (2006).
7
Chitika (2013) The value of Google result positioning. Available at perma.cc/7AGC-HTDH. Accessed June 30, 2015.
8
Optify (2011) The changing face of SERPS: Organic CTR. Available at perma.cc/KZ5X-78TL. Accessed June 30, 2015.
9
BJ Jansen, A Spink, T Saracevic, Real life, real users, and real needs: A study and analysis of user queries on the web. Inf Process Manage 36, 207–227 (2000).
10
A Spink, D Wolfram, BJ Jansen, T Saracevic, Searching the web: The public and their queries. J Am Soc Inf Sci Technol 53, 226–234 (2001).
11
C Silverstein, H Marais, M Henzinger, A Moricz, Analysis of a very large web search engine query log. Association for Computing Machinery Special Interest Group on Information Retrieval Forum 33(1):6–12. (1999).
12
K Purcell, J Brenner, L Rainie, Pew Research Center’s Internet & American Life project: Search engine use 2012. Available at perma.cc/NF6C-JCPW. Accessed June 30, 2015. (2012).
13
M Learmonth, What big brands are spending on Google. Available at perma.cc/5L3B-SPTX. Accessed June 30, 2015. (2010).
14
Econsultancy (2012) SEMPO state of search marketing report 2012. Available at perma.cc/A3KH-6QVB. Accessed June 30, 2015.
15
S Gerhart, Do Web search engines suppress controversy? First Monday 9, 1111 (2004).
16
H Ebbinghaus Memory: A Contribution to Experimental Psychology (No. 3) (Teachers College, Columbia Univ, New York, 1913).
17
BB Murdock, The serial position effect of free recall. J Exp Psychol 64, 482–488 (1962).
18
SE Asch, Forming impressions of personality. J Abnorm Psychol 41, 258–290 (1946).
19
FH Lund, The psychology of belief. J Abnorm Soc Psych 20, 63–81 (1925).
20
CI Hovland The Order of Presentation in Persuasion (Yale Univ Press, New Haven, CT, 1957).
21
JE Baird, RC Zelin, The effects of information ordering on investor perceptions: An experiment utilizing presidents’ letters. J Financial Strategic Decisions 13, 71–80 (2000).
22
R Tourangeau, MP Couper, FG Conrad, “Up means good” The effect of screen position on evaluative ratings in web surveys. Public Opin Q 77, 69–88 (2013).
23
JA Krosnick, DF Alwin, An evaluation of a cognitive theory of response order effects in survey measurement. Pub Op Quarterly 51, 201–219 (1987).
24
MJ Stern, DA Dillman, JD Smyth, Visual design, order effects, and respondent characteristics in a self-administered survey. Surv Res Methods 1, 121–138 (2007).
25
JE Miller Menu Pricing and Strategy (CBI Publishing, Boston, 1980).
26
DE Ho, K Imai, Estimating causal effects of ballot order from a randomized natural experiment the California alphabet lottery, 1978–2002. Pub Op Quarterly 72, 216–240 (2008).
27
E Chen, G Simonovits, JA Krosnick, J Pasek, The impact of candidate name order on election outcomes in North Dakota. Elect Stud 35, 115–122 (2014).
28
JA Krosnick, JM Miller, MP Tichy, An unrecognized need for ballot reform. Rethinking the Vote , eds A Crigler, M Just, E McCaffery (Oxford Univ Press, New York), pp. 51–74 (2004).
29
JG Koppell, JA Steen, The effects of ballot position on election outcomes. J Polit 66, 267–281 (2004).
30
N Kim, JA Krosnick, D Casasanto, Moderators of candidate name-order effects in elections: An experiment. Polit Psychol , 2014).
31
JM Miller, JA Krosnick, The impact of candidate name order on election outcomes. Pub Op Quarterly 62, 291–330 (1998).
32
J Pasek, et al., Prevalence and moderators of the candidate name-order effect evidence from statewide general elections in California. Pub Op Quarterly 78, 416–439 (2014).
33
J Murphy, C Hofacker, R Mizerski, Primacy and recency effects on clicking behavior. J Comput Mediat Commun 11, 522–535 (2006).
34
A Ansari, CF Mela, E-customization. J Mark Res 40, 131–145 (2003).
35
X Drèze, F Zufryden, Measurement of online visibility and its impact on Internet traffic. J Interact Market 18, 20–37 (2004).
36
CF Chiang, BG Knight, Media bias and influence: Evidence from newspaper endorsements. Rev Econ Stud 78, 795–820 (2011).
37
JN Druckman, M Parkin, The impact of media bias: How editorial slant affects voters. J Polit 67, 1030–1049 (2005).
38
A Gerber, DS Karlan, D Bergan, Does the media matter? A field experiment measuring the effect of newspapers on voting behavior and political opinions. Am Econ J Appl Econ 1, 35–52 (2009).
39
VG Morwitz, C Pluzinski, Do pools reflect opinions or do opinions reflect polls? The impact of political polling on voters’ expectation, preferences, and behavior. J Consum Res 23, 53–67 (1996).
40
S DellaVigna, E Kaplan, The Fox News effect: Media bias and voting. Q J Econ 122, 1187–1234 (2007).
41
G Lakoff Women, Fire and Dangerous Things (Univ of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1987).
42
PM DeMarzo, D Vayanos, J Zwiebel, Persuasion bias, social influence, and unidimensional opinions. Q J Econ 118, 909–968 (2003).
43
BJ Fogg Persuasive Technology: Using Computers to Change What We Think and Do (Morgan Kaufmann, San Francisco, 2002).
44
RM Bond, et al., A 61-million-person experiment in social influence and political mobilization. Nature 489, 295–298 (2012).
45
J Zittrain, Engineering an election. Digital gerrymandering poses a threat to democracy. Harvard Law Review Forum 127, 335–341 (2014).
46
US Census Bureau (2011) Voting and registration in the election of November 2010. Available at perma.cc/DU9N-C6XT. Accessed June 30, 2015.
47
EF Loftus Eyewitness Testimony (Harvard Univ Press, Boston, 1996).
48
A Kühberger, A Fritz, T Scherndl, Publication bias in psychology: A diagnosis based on the correlation between effect size and sample size. PLoS One 9, e105825 (2014).
49
G Paolacci, J Chandler, Inside the Turk: Understanding mechanical Turk as a participant pool. Curr Dir Psychol Sci 23, 184–188 (2014).
50
AJ Berinsky, GA Huber, GS Lenz, Evaluating online labor markets for experimental research: Amazon.com’s mechanical turk. Polit Anal 20, 351–368 (2012).
51
GJ Gates, How many people are lesbian, gay, bisexual and transgender? Available at perma.cc/N7P2-TXHV. Accessed June 30, 2015. (2011).
52
A Gelman, J Hill Data Analysis Using Regression and Multilevel/Hierarchical Models (Cambridge Univ Press, Boston, 2006).
53
Census of India (2011) Population enumeration data. Available at perma.cc/4JKF-UWQZ. Accessed June 30, 2015.
54
HA Simon, Bandwagon and underdog effects and the possibility of election predictions. Pub Op Quarterly 18, 245–253 (1954).
55
D Leip, Dave Leip’s atlas of U.S. presidential elections. Available at perma.cc/G9YF-6CPE. Accessed June 30, 2015. (2012).
56
D Rogers, F Cage, US house and senate elections 2012. Available at perma.cc/5QSK-FNCL. Accessed June 30, 2015. (2012).
57
Cabletelevision Advertising Bureau (2012) CAB undecided voters study 2012. Available at perma.cc/T82K-YC38. Accessed June 30, 2015.
58
J Rutenberg, Obama campaign endgame: Grunt work and cold math. Available at perma.cc/X74D-YNM5. Accessed June 30, 2015. (2012).
59
GW Cox, MD McCubbins, Electoral politics as a redistributive game. J Polit 48, 370–389 (1986).
60
A Lindbeck, JW Weibull, Balanced-budget redistribution as the outcome of political competition. Public Choice 52, 273–297 (1987).
61
A Smith, Pew Research Center’s Internet & American Life Project: The Internet and campaign 2010. Available at perma.cc/3U9R-EUQQ. Accessed June 30, 2015. (2011).
62
A Smith, M Duggan, Pew Research Center’s Internet & American life project: Online political videos and campaign 2012. Available at perma.cc/5UX2-LELJ. Accessed June 30, 2015. (2012).
63
Cisco (2014) VNI Global IP Traffic Forecast, 2013–2018. Available at perma.cc/AE9R-JSHL. Accessed June 30, 2015.
64
T Ash, M Ginty, R Page Landing Page Optimization: The Definitive Guide to Testing and Tuning for Conversions (John Wiley & Sons, Indianapolis, 2012).
65
SJ Kraus, Attitudes and the prediction of behavior: A meta-analysis of the empirical literature. Pers Soc Psychol Bull 21, 58–75 (1995).
66
RB Zajonc, Mere exposure: A gateway to the subliminal. Curr Dir Psychol Sci 10, 224–228 (2001).
67
J Berger, G Fitzsimons, Dogs on the street, pumas on your feet: How cues in the environment influence product evaluation and choice. J Mark Res 45, 1–14 (2008).
68
SA Brasel, J Gips, Red bull “gives you wings” for better or worse: A double-edged impact of brand exposure on consumer performance. J Consum Psychol 21, 57–64 (2011).
69
ML Fransen, BM Fennis, ATH Pruyn, E Das, Rest in peace? Brand-induced mortality salience and consumer behavior. J Bus Res 64, 1053–1061 (2008).
70
JA Bargh, PM Gollwitzer, A Lee-Chai, K Barndollar, R Trötschel, The automated will: Nonconscious activation and pursuit of behavioral goals. J Pers Soc Psychol 81, 1014–1027 (2001).
71
E Pronin, MB Kugler, Valuing thoughts, ignoring behavior: The introspection illusion as a source of the bias blind spot. J Exp Soc Psychol 43, 565–578 (2007).
72
P Winkielman, KC Berridge, JL Wilbarger, Unconscious affective reactions to masked happy versus angry faces influence consumption behavior and judgments of value. Pers Soc Psychol Bull 31, 121–135 (2005).
73
JC Karremans, W Stroebe, J Claus, Beyond Vicary’s fantasies: The impact of subliminal priming and brand choice. J Exp Soc Psychol 42, 792–798 (2006).
74
JB Légal, J Chappé, V Coiffard, A Villard-Forest, Don’t you know that you want to trust me? Subliminal goal priming and persuasion. J Exp Soc Psychol 48, 358–360 (2012).
75
J Mills, E Aronson, Opinion change as a function of the communicator’s attractiveness and desire to influence. J Pers Soc Psychol 1, 173–177 (1965).
76
B Bi, M Shokouhi, M Kosinski, T Graepel, Inferring the demographics of search users: Social data meets search queries. Proceedings of the 22nd International Conference on World Wide Web (International World Wide Web Conferences Steering Committee, Republic and Canton of Geneva, Switzerland), pp 131–140. (2013).
77
Yan J, et al. (2009, April). How much can behavioral targeting help online advertising? Proceedings of the 18th International Conference on World Wide Web (ACM, New York), pp 261–270.
78
I Weber, C Castillo, The demographics of web search. Proceedings of the 33rd Annual International Association for Computing Machinery Special Interest Group on Information Retrieval Conference on Research and Development in Information Retrieval (ACM, New York), pp 523–530. (2010).
79
WG Mayer The Swing Voter in American Politics (Brookings Institution Press, Washington, DC, 2008).
80
GW Cox, Swing voters, core voters, and distributive politics. Political Representation , eds I Shapiro, SC Stokes, EJ Wood, AS Kirshner (Cambridge Univ Press, Cambridge, MA), pp. 342–357 (2010).
81
KN Bickers, RM Stein, The electoral dynamics of the federal pork barrel. Am J Pol Sci 40, 1300–1325 (1996).
82
M Dahlberg, E Johansson, On the vote-purchasing behavior of incumbent governments. Am Polit Sci Rev 96, 27–40 (2002).
83
RM Stein, KN Bickers, Congressional Elections and the Pork Barrel. J Polit 56, 377–399 (1994).
84
SC Stokes, Perverse accountability: A formal model of machine politics with evidence from Argentina. Am Polit Sci Rev 99, 315–325 (2005).
85
WG Mayer, The disappearing–but still important–swing voter. Forum 10, 1520 (2012).
86
E Agichtein, E Brill, S Dumais, Improving web search ranking by incorporating user behavior information. Proceedings of the 29th Annual International Association for Computing Machinery Special Interest Group on Information Retrieval Conference on Research and Development in Information Retrieval (ACM, New York), pp 19–26. (2006).
87
A Ahmed, M Aly, A Das, AJ Smola, T Anastasakos, Web-scale multi-task feature selection for behavioral targeting. Proceedings of the 21st Association for Computing Machinery International Conference on Information and Knowledge Management (ACM, New York), pp 1737–1741. (2012).
88
Y Chen, D Pavlov, JF Canny, Large-scale behavioral targeting. Proceedings of the 15th Association for Computing Machinery Special Interest Group on Knowledge Discovery in Data International Conference on Knowledge Discovery and Data Mining (ACM, New York), pp 209–218. (2009).
89
N Höchstötter, D Lewandowski, What users see—Structures in search engine results pages. Inf Sci 179, 1796–1812 (2009).
90
L Page, S Brin, R Motwani, T Winograd The PageRank Citation Ranking: Bringing Order to the Web. Technical Report (Stanford InfoLab, Palo Alto, CA, 1999).